1 00:00:00,060 --> 00:00:02,500 The following content is provided under a Creative 2 00:00:02,500 --> 00:00:04,019 Commons license. 3 00:00:04,019 --> 00:00:06,360 Your support will help MIT OpenCourseWare 4 00:00:06,360 --> 00:00:10,730 continue to offer high-quality educational resources for free. 5 00:00:10,730 --> 00:00:13,340 To make a donation or view additional materials 6 00:00:13,340 --> 00:00:17,217 from hundreds of MIT courses, visit MIT OpenCourseWare 7 00:00:17,217 --> 00:00:17,842 at ocw.mit.edu. 8 00:00:21,860 --> 00:00:26,390 PROFESSOR: All right, OK, let's get started. 9 00:00:26,390 --> 00:00:28,450 So before I make introduction, let me just 10 00:00:28,450 --> 00:00:30,670 make a few announcements. 11 00:00:30,670 --> 00:00:37,000 A few of you came to us asking about the grading for the term. 12 00:00:37,000 --> 00:00:41,520 And some feel the problem sets may be on the difficult side, 13 00:00:41,520 --> 00:00:45,670 and some of you haven't done all of them, and some of you 14 00:00:45,670 --> 00:00:46,970 have done more. 15 00:00:46,970 --> 00:00:50,720 So we just want to let you know that the most important thing 16 00:00:50,720 --> 00:00:56,280 to us in grading is really you show your effort in terms 17 00:00:56,280 --> 00:00:57,220 of learning. 18 00:00:57,220 --> 00:00:59,280 And we purposely made the problem 19 00:00:59,280 --> 00:01:01,740 sets more difficult than the lecture, 20 00:01:01,740 --> 00:01:05,080 so you can-- if you want to dig in deeper so you have 21 00:01:05,080 --> 00:01:06,820 the opportunity to learn more. 22 00:01:06,820 --> 00:01:11,310 But by no means we expect you to finish 23 00:01:11,310 --> 00:01:17,980 or feel easy in solving all the problem sets. 24 00:01:17,980 --> 00:01:20,390 So I just want to put you at ease 25 00:01:20,390 --> 00:01:24,080 that if that's your concern, that's definitely-- 26 00:01:24,080 --> 00:01:25,610 you don't need to worry about it. 27 00:01:25,610 --> 00:01:31,800 And we will be really just evaluating your effort. 28 00:01:31,800 --> 00:01:35,260 And based on what do we observed so far, 29 00:01:35,260 --> 00:01:38,770 we actually believe every single one of you is doing quite well. 30 00:01:38,770 --> 00:01:44,060 So you shouldn't worry about your performance at the class. 31 00:01:44,060 --> 00:01:49,120 So continue to do a good job on your class participation, 32 00:01:49,120 --> 00:01:51,250 and do some of the problem sets. 33 00:01:51,250 --> 00:01:53,970 And then you will be in fine shape for your grade. 34 00:01:53,970 --> 00:01:56,130 So that's all of that. 35 00:01:56,130 --> 00:01:58,340 So without any further delay, let 36 00:01:58,340 --> 00:02:02,480 me introduce my colleague, Doctor Stephen Blythe. 37 00:02:02,480 --> 00:02:03,720 I'll be very brief. 38 00:02:03,720 --> 00:02:09,160 And he's-- Stephen is doing two jobs at the same time. 39 00:02:09,160 --> 00:02:14,430 He's responsible for the all the public markets at Harvard 40 00:02:14,430 --> 00:02:19,100 Management, as well as being a professor of practice 41 00:02:19,100 --> 00:02:20,070 at Harvard. 42 00:02:20,070 --> 00:02:21,962 So with that, I turn to Stephen. 43 00:02:21,962 --> 00:02:24,300 STEPHEN BLYTHE: OK, well, thank you, and thank you 44 00:02:24,300 --> 00:02:26,720 for having me to speak this afternoon. 45 00:02:26,720 --> 00:02:33,640 Before I begin, I wanted to ask you a question. 46 00:02:33,640 --> 00:02:36,830 So I'm speaking, actually, at almost exactly 47 00:02:36,830 --> 00:02:39,640 the 20th anniversary of something very important. 48 00:02:39,640 --> 00:02:44,660 So on the 19th of October, 1993, which I guess 49 00:02:44,660 --> 00:02:46,680 might be the birthday of some of you, 50 00:02:46,680 --> 00:02:54,471 but almost exactly 20 years ago, Congress voted 264 to 159-- 51 00:02:54,471 --> 00:02:58,340 I actually remember the count of the vote-- to do something. 52 00:02:58,340 --> 00:03:01,820 So anybody like to guess what they 53 00:03:01,820 --> 00:03:05,190 voted to do on the 19th of October, 1993 that 54 00:03:05,190 --> 00:03:07,900 might be tangentially relevant to finance 55 00:03:07,900 --> 00:03:10,570 and quantitative finance? 56 00:03:10,570 --> 00:03:12,510 Anyone here from HMC is not allowed to answer. 57 00:03:12,510 --> 00:03:15,160 Anybody-- any guesses? 58 00:03:15,160 --> 00:03:17,970 Any ideas at all coming to people's minds? 59 00:03:17,970 --> 00:03:19,470 AUDIENCE: Was it Gramm-Leach-Bliley? 60 00:03:19,470 --> 00:03:20,424 STEPHEN BLYTHE: No. 61 00:03:20,424 --> 00:03:22,340 AUDIENCE: Commodity Futures Modernization Act? 62 00:03:22,340 --> 00:03:24,880 STEPHEN BLYTHE: No, but good guess. 63 00:03:24,880 --> 00:03:27,380 But actually, that is actually too related to finance, 64 00:03:27,380 --> 00:03:27,880 actually. 65 00:03:27,880 --> 00:03:29,979 This is actually-- wasn't actually 66 00:03:29,979 --> 00:03:31,520 directly financially related, so that 67 00:03:31,520 --> 00:03:32,850 was related to [INAUDIBLE]. 68 00:03:32,850 --> 00:03:34,330 Anybody else think about? 69 00:03:37,360 --> 00:03:38,640 What does Congress usually do? 70 00:03:42,104 --> 00:03:43,020 AUDIENCE: [INAUDIBLE]. 71 00:03:43,020 --> 00:03:45,679 [LAUGHTER] 72 00:03:45,679 --> 00:03:47,345 STEPHEN BLYTHE: No, no ideas whatsoever? 73 00:03:58,727 --> 00:04:00,560 What do you think Congress did 20 years ago? 74 00:04:00,560 --> 00:04:03,544 They voted to do something. 75 00:04:03,544 --> 00:04:04,960 OK, well, what Congress do usually 76 00:04:04,960 --> 00:04:06,293 is they cut money for something. 77 00:04:06,293 --> 00:04:10,070 So they voted to cut financing to something. 78 00:04:10,070 --> 00:04:12,240 So what did they cut financing to? 79 00:04:12,240 --> 00:04:14,694 Anybody guess? 80 00:04:14,694 --> 00:04:16,110 I know this isn't business school. 81 00:04:16,110 --> 00:04:18,100 In business school, it would be, like, right, you're failed. 82 00:04:18,100 --> 00:04:20,100 No class participation-- you failed. 83 00:04:20,100 --> 00:04:22,190 You've got to say something in business school. 84 00:04:22,190 --> 00:04:23,270 So I know it's not business school. 85 00:04:23,270 --> 00:04:25,686 But anyway-- and I don't teach in business school, either. 86 00:04:25,686 --> 00:04:27,570 But this is actually-- these round 87 00:04:27,570 --> 00:04:29,310 desks make me think of business school 88 00:04:29,310 --> 00:04:32,010 and striding into the middle of the room, 89 00:04:32,010 --> 00:04:33,630 and saying OK, come on. 90 00:04:33,630 --> 00:04:36,710 Fortunately, I don't have names, otherwise I'd pick on you. 91 00:04:36,710 --> 00:04:39,784 No, no guesses-- no guesses whatsoever? 92 00:04:39,784 --> 00:04:41,950 I've got to take this up the road to Harvard Square, 93 00:04:41,950 --> 00:04:43,800 and say I've taught at MIT. 94 00:04:43,800 --> 00:04:46,140 No one had any guesses with this question-- one guess, 95 00:04:46,140 --> 00:04:47,910 actually, the gentleman here. 96 00:04:47,910 --> 00:04:54,140 What did they cancel the financing for in 1993? 97 00:04:54,140 --> 00:04:57,050 I'll say it was the Superconducting Super 98 00:04:57,050 --> 00:05:02,210 Collider underneath Texas just south of Dallas. 99 00:05:02,210 --> 00:05:06,505 So $2 billion had been spent on the Super Collider. 100 00:05:06,505 --> 00:05:08,350 And the budget had expanded from, I think, 101 00:05:08,350 --> 00:05:09,300 $6 to $11 billion. 102 00:05:09,300 --> 00:05:11,680 So they, by canceling, had a $9 billion dollar savings. 103 00:05:11,680 --> 00:05:14,990 This is 20 years ago-- almost exactly. 104 00:05:14,990 --> 00:05:17,440 And as a result of that-- one result of that-- was, 105 00:05:17,440 --> 00:05:20,390 of course, the academic job market for physicists 106 00:05:20,390 --> 00:05:22,700 collapsed overnight. 107 00:05:22,700 --> 00:05:26,360 And two of my roommates were theoretical physicists 108 00:05:26,360 --> 00:05:27,470 at Harvard. 109 00:05:27,470 --> 00:05:30,990 And they basically realized their job prospects in academia 110 00:05:30,990 --> 00:05:33,960 had vaporized instantaneously that day. 111 00:05:33,960 --> 00:05:36,530 And both of them, within six months, 112 00:05:36,530 --> 00:05:40,820 had found jobs with Goldman Sachs in New York. 113 00:05:40,820 --> 00:05:44,340 And they catalyzed they-- they and the cohort-- 114 00:05:44,340 --> 00:05:46,740 they're called the Superconducting Super Collider 115 00:05:46,740 --> 00:05:47,940 generation. 116 00:05:47,940 --> 00:05:51,230 If you ever wondered why people like myself and like Jake got 117 00:05:51,230 --> 00:05:54,680 PhDs in quantitative subjects around the turn of-- around 118 00:05:54,680 --> 00:05:59,070 1990 to 1993-- all ended up in a financial path, 119 00:05:59,070 --> 00:06:01,630 part of it is due to Congress cancelling the Superconducting 120 00:06:01,630 --> 00:06:02,254 Super Collider. 121 00:06:02,254 --> 00:06:04,720 Because this cohort catalyzed this growth 122 00:06:04,720 --> 00:06:06,310 in quantitative finance. 123 00:06:06,310 --> 00:06:09,680 Actually, they created a field-- financial engineering-- 124 00:06:09,680 --> 00:06:12,730 which you are all somewhat interested in by taking 125 00:06:12,730 --> 00:06:13,970 this class. 126 00:06:13,970 --> 00:06:17,770 And they also created a career path-- quantitative analyst, 127 00:06:17,770 --> 00:06:21,790 or quant, which really did not exist before 1993. 128 00:06:21,790 --> 00:06:26,485 And that growth of mathematical finance, 129 00:06:26,485 --> 00:06:28,360 financial engineering, quantitative finance-- 130 00:06:28,360 --> 00:06:29,900 however you want to look at it-- was 131 00:06:29,900 --> 00:06:32,460 basically exponential from 1993 up 132 00:06:32,460 --> 00:06:37,610 until 2008 and the financial crisis exactly five years ago, 133 00:06:37,610 --> 00:06:38,840 funnily enough. 134 00:06:38,840 --> 00:06:41,160 And since then, it's been a little bit rockier. 135 00:06:41,160 --> 00:06:43,450 So if you're actually interested in this aftermath 136 00:06:43,450 --> 00:06:46,140 of the physics funding-- what's interesting is the Large Hadron 137 00:06:46,140 --> 00:06:48,980 Collider, which you might know is up and running in Geneva 138 00:06:48,980 --> 00:06:51,720 and just found the Higgs Boson, has sort of 139 00:06:51,720 --> 00:06:53,280 reversed the trend somewhat. 140 00:06:53,280 --> 00:06:54,990 So there used to be a whole cohort 141 00:06:54,990 --> 00:06:57,260 of people going into finance instead of physics. 142 00:06:57,260 --> 00:07:00,360 Now, because finance has this somewhat pejorative nature 143 00:07:00,360 --> 00:07:02,780 to it-- people don't like bankers generally, 144 00:07:02,780 --> 00:07:05,170 and they kind of like physicists who find the Higgs Boson 145 00:07:05,170 --> 00:07:07,690 and get a Nobel Prize-- maybe we're getting reversal. 146 00:07:07,690 --> 00:07:10,190 But anyway, we're still in finance. 147 00:07:10,190 --> 00:07:14,640 I've, as Jake mentioned, well, I did mention, 148 00:07:14,640 --> 00:07:16,170 I was originally in academics. 149 00:07:16,170 --> 00:07:19,360 I was actually a mathematics faculty member in London 150 00:07:19,360 --> 00:07:21,570 when I got my PhD-- I got my PhD from Harvard. 151 00:07:21,570 --> 00:07:23,164 And in 1993, I was an academic. 152 00:07:23,164 --> 00:07:25,080 And all my friends-- I saw them go to finance. 153 00:07:25,080 --> 00:07:27,940 So I followed them, spent a career in New York, 154 00:07:27,940 --> 00:07:31,120 and then came back to Harvard in 2006 155 00:07:31,120 --> 00:07:32,790 to run a part of the endowment. 156 00:07:32,790 --> 00:07:34,580 And I started teaching. 157 00:07:34,580 --> 00:07:37,745 So just as a plug-- for those of you 158 00:07:37,745 --> 00:07:39,870 interested in mathematical finance and applications 159 00:07:39,870 --> 00:07:42,320 of mathematics finance, I teach a course at Harvard. 160 00:07:42,320 --> 00:07:44,740 It's an upper level undergraduate course 161 00:07:44,740 --> 00:07:47,310 called Applied Quantitative Finance, which of course you 162 00:07:47,310 --> 00:07:49,770 can cross-register for. 163 00:07:49,770 --> 00:07:53,130 And today is also the one-week anniversary 164 00:07:53,130 --> 00:07:54,820 of the publication of my book. 165 00:07:54,820 --> 00:07:59,029 So if you're interested in what my course is about, 166 00:07:59,029 --> 00:08:00,070 you can just buy my book. 167 00:08:00,070 --> 00:08:01,612 It's only $30. 168 00:08:01,612 --> 00:08:02,320 And I'll sign it. 169 00:08:02,320 --> 00:08:04,500 It's first edition, first printing, 170 00:08:04,500 --> 00:08:06,410 first impression book, Introduction 171 00:08:06,410 --> 00:08:09,270 to Quantitative Finance. 172 00:08:09,270 --> 00:08:10,890 And that is what the course is. 173 00:08:10,890 --> 00:08:12,240 It's quite distilled. 174 00:08:12,240 --> 00:08:15,470 When this book came out, I thought, that's really thin. 175 00:08:15,470 --> 00:08:17,639 This is three years of my life's work. 176 00:08:17,639 --> 00:08:18,930 It's come out-- it's very thin. 177 00:08:18,930 --> 00:08:20,513 But I like to think it's like whiskey. 178 00:08:20,513 --> 00:08:23,140 It's well distilled, and highly potent, 179 00:08:23,140 --> 00:08:25,400 and you have to sip it, and take it bit by bit. 180 00:08:25,400 --> 00:08:27,910 Anyway, that is the book of my class. 181 00:08:27,910 --> 00:08:35,090 And the genesis of the class was really 182 00:08:35,090 --> 00:08:37,162 that, when I've been on Wall Street, 183 00:08:37,162 --> 00:08:38,870 and I was a colleague of Jake's at Morgan 184 00:08:38,870 --> 00:08:46,460 Stanley in this rapidly growing quantitative finance field, 185 00:08:46,460 --> 00:08:48,870 we encountered on the trading desk in the late 1990s 186 00:08:48,870 --> 00:08:53,820 and the early 2000s problems from the real economy-- things 187 00:08:53,820 --> 00:08:55,050 that we had to trade. 188 00:08:55,050 --> 00:08:57,880 We were-- things that were coming to us on the trading 189 00:08:57,880 --> 00:09:03,200 desk that required subtle understanding of the underlying 190 00:09:03,200 --> 00:09:03,980 theory. 191 00:09:03,980 --> 00:09:09,929 So that we, in essence, we built theoretical framework 192 00:09:09,929 --> 00:09:11,470 to solve the problems that were given 193 00:09:11,470 --> 00:09:13,480 to us by the financial markets. 194 00:09:13,480 --> 00:09:17,150 So that period, especially around the turn of the century, 195 00:09:17,150 --> 00:09:20,750 there's a big growth in derivatives markets, which-- 196 00:09:20,750 --> 00:09:25,460 options, futures, forwards, et cetera, swaps. 197 00:09:25,460 --> 00:09:27,426 And we needed to build theoretical tools 198 00:09:27,426 --> 00:09:28,050 to tackle them. 199 00:09:28,050 --> 00:09:31,640 And that's really what the course was evolved out of, 200 00:09:31,640 --> 00:09:34,090 to build the appropriate theoretical framework, 201 00:09:34,090 --> 00:09:37,040 motivated by the problems we encountered. 202 00:09:37,040 --> 00:09:40,694 Why I enthuse about the subject-- 203 00:09:40,694 --> 00:09:42,360 and I really like teaching the subject-- 204 00:09:42,360 --> 00:09:46,052 is that there is an impression that qualitative finance is 205 00:09:46,052 --> 00:09:49,720 a very arcane and contrived subject-- just a whole 206 00:09:49,720 --> 00:09:52,799 bunch of PhDs on Wall Street coming up with crazy ideas. 207 00:09:52,799 --> 00:09:54,340 And they need complicated mathematics 208 00:09:54,340 --> 00:09:56,620 that's just complicated for the sake of complexity. 209 00:09:56,620 --> 00:09:59,570 And the theory is just sort of a contrived theory. 210 00:09:59,570 --> 00:10:02,400 But in fact, at the heart of Wall Street 211 00:10:02,400 --> 00:10:05,275 is that the real economy demands some of these products 212 00:10:05,275 --> 00:10:06,150 by supply and demand. 213 00:10:06,150 --> 00:10:07,960 There are actual, real participants 214 00:10:07,960 --> 00:10:09,790 in the financial markets who want to trade derivatives. 215 00:10:09,790 --> 00:10:11,500 And therefore, in order to understand them, 216 00:10:11,500 --> 00:10:12,708 you need to develop a theory. 217 00:10:12,708 --> 00:10:15,420 So it's actually driven by real examples. 218 00:10:15,420 --> 00:10:16,860 That's one part. 219 00:10:16,860 --> 00:10:19,320 The other part is that the theory that comes out 220 00:10:19,320 --> 00:10:21,810 of it, and in particular the approach I take here, I think 221 00:10:21,810 --> 00:10:23,234 is just very elegant. 222 00:10:23,234 --> 00:10:25,400 OK, so there's some subtlety and elegance and beauty 223 00:10:25,400 --> 00:10:28,410 to the underlying theory that comes out 224 00:10:28,410 --> 00:10:30,870 of addressing real problems. 225 00:10:30,870 --> 00:10:34,830 This course, and the way that I teach finance, 226 00:10:34,830 --> 00:10:37,340 is very probability centric. 227 00:10:37,340 --> 00:10:40,220 You probably realize from the lectures you've seen already 228 00:10:40,220 --> 00:10:43,350 in this class, there are many different approaches, 229 00:10:43,350 --> 00:10:46,350 many different methods that are used in finance-- stochastic 230 00:10:46,350 --> 00:10:48,640 calculus, partial differential equations, simulation, 231 00:10:48,640 --> 00:10:50,170 and so on. 232 00:10:50,170 --> 00:10:53,140 The classical derivation of Black-Scholes 233 00:10:53,140 --> 00:10:56,700 is, well, it's the solution of the PDE. 234 00:10:56,700 --> 00:10:59,374 OK, that has appealed to people. 235 00:10:59,374 --> 00:11:00,790 In fact, this is why in some ways, 236 00:11:00,790 --> 00:11:02,414 quantitative finance is a broad church, 237 00:11:02,414 --> 00:11:05,280 because whether you're a physicist, or probabilist, 238 00:11:05,280 --> 00:11:08,910 or a chemical engineer, all the techniques you learn 239 00:11:08,910 --> 00:11:09,652 can be applied. 240 00:11:09,652 --> 00:11:10,860 You know stochastic calculus. 241 00:11:10,860 --> 00:11:12,610 You know differential equations. 242 00:11:12,610 --> 00:11:13,900 They can be applied. 243 00:11:13,900 --> 00:11:15,940 But the path that I take in this class 244 00:11:15,940 --> 00:11:19,770 is very much through the probabilistic route, which 245 00:11:19,770 --> 00:11:23,580 is my background as a probabilist, as 246 00:11:23,580 --> 00:11:25,800 an academic, or a statistician as an academic. 247 00:11:25,800 --> 00:11:28,905 And this is, in particular, I think, a very elegant path 248 00:11:28,905 --> 00:11:30,770 to understand finance, and the linkage 249 00:11:30,770 --> 00:11:32,480 between derivative products-- which 250 00:11:32,480 --> 00:11:34,910 might seem contrived-- and probability distributions, 251 00:11:34,910 --> 00:11:37,250 which is sort of natural things for probabilists. 252 00:11:37,250 --> 00:11:39,810 So this, what we're going to talk about today, 253 00:11:39,810 --> 00:11:44,340 is really this link, which I call 254 00:11:44,340 --> 00:11:52,870 option-probability duality. 255 00:11:52,870 --> 00:11:58,660 Which, in essence, in the simplest form, is just saying, 256 00:11:58,660 --> 00:12:00,970 option prices-- they're just probability distributions. 257 00:12:00,970 --> 00:12:03,199 Therefore, these complicated derivatives 258 00:12:03,199 --> 00:12:04,990 that people talk about-- all these options, 259 00:12:04,990 --> 00:12:06,906 these financial engineers, these quants, these 260 00:12:06,906 --> 00:12:09,130 exotics-- we're really just talking about probability 261 00:12:09,130 --> 00:12:09,713 distributions. 262 00:12:09,713 --> 00:12:12,680 We can go between them-- option prices, probabilities, 263 00:12:12,680 --> 00:12:15,600 and distributions-- back and forth in a very elegant way. 264 00:12:15,600 --> 00:12:18,180 What I love about this subject in particular 265 00:12:18,180 --> 00:12:22,070 is that to get to that point where we see this duality does 266 00:12:22,070 --> 00:12:27,310 not need a whole framework and infrastructure 267 00:12:27,310 --> 00:12:32,679 of complicated definitions, or formulae, or option pricing 268 00:12:32,679 --> 00:12:33,470 formulae, or so on. 269 00:12:33,470 --> 00:12:36,080 So that's what I'm going to try and do in this hour or so, 270 00:12:36,080 --> 00:12:39,750 is introduce this concept of option price, probability 271 00:12:39,750 --> 00:12:40,380 duality. 272 00:12:40,380 --> 00:12:42,974 And show how the natural-- so there's 273 00:12:42,974 --> 00:12:44,390 a natural duality that can be seen 274 00:12:44,390 --> 00:12:45,860 in a number of different ways. 275 00:12:45,860 --> 00:12:49,870 OK, so we're going to need a few definitions that 276 00:12:49,870 --> 00:12:52,137 should be familiar to you. 277 00:12:52,137 --> 00:12:53,595 We're going to define three assets. 278 00:12:56,300 --> 00:13:00,306 We have a call option, which we know about, 279 00:13:00,306 --> 00:13:06,659 a zero-coupon bond-- called a zed cee bee. 280 00:13:06,659 --> 00:13:08,950 This is the one thing I haven't become Americanized on. 281 00:13:08,950 --> 00:13:10,400 I still call this zed. 282 00:13:10,400 --> 00:13:13,410 It's a-- other things I've become-- 283 00:13:13,410 --> 00:13:15,480 and then a digital option. 284 00:13:19,190 --> 00:13:21,830 OK, all right, so what are they? 285 00:13:21,830 --> 00:13:24,880 Well, they're all going to be defined by their payouts 286 00:13:24,880 --> 00:13:26,260 at maturity. 287 00:13:26,260 --> 00:13:29,180 OK, so we're going to have some maturity capital T, 288 00:13:29,180 --> 00:13:33,700 and some underlying asset, S, the stock, with some price S_T. 289 00:13:33,700 --> 00:13:36,770 OK, so we know that the call option has payout at T-- 290 00:13:36,770 --> 00:13:41,260 So that's called payout at T. So T is 291 00:13:41,260 --> 00:13:43,090 some fixed time in the future. 292 00:13:43,090 --> 00:13:45,930 We will change in the future to some fixed time. 293 00:13:45,930 --> 00:13:53,940 This is simply the max of S_T minus K and 0. 294 00:13:53,940 --> 00:13:56,830 That's a call option. 295 00:13:56,830 --> 00:14:00,021 You can go through the right to buy, et cetera, et cetera. 296 00:14:00,021 --> 00:14:01,770 But it's clear it's just value at maturity 297 00:14:01,770 --> 00:14:05,530 is just the max of S_T minus K and 0. 298 00:14:05,530 --> 00:14:09,450 The zero-coupon bond with maturity T 299 00:14:09,450 --> 00:14:11,840 is just something that's worth 1 at time T. 300 00:14:11,840 --> 00:14:15,181 So that's just payout one. 301 00:14:15,181 --> 00:14:16,680 That's definition-- so you can think 302 00:14:16,680 --> 00:14:18,760 of these all as definitions. 303 00:14:18,760 --> 00:14:21,220 And then the digital option is just 304 00:14:21,220 --> 00:14:31,760 the indicator function of S_T being greater than K. So here, 305 00:14:31,760 --> 00:14:33,170 T is the maturity. 306 00:14:33,170 --> 00:14:36,055 K is the strike. 307 00:14:36,055 --> 00:14:41,510 So T maturity, K is strike. 308 00:14:44,540 --> 00:14:46,920 And these are three assets. 309 00:14:46,920 --> 00:14:49,540 So this is, in some sense, the payout function. 310 00:14:49,540 --> 00:14:51,650 All derivative products can be defined 311 00:14:51,650 --> 00:14:54,150 in terms of a function-- not all of them. 312 00:14:54,150 --> 00:14:56,170 Many derivative products can be defined just 313 00:14:56,170 --> 00:14:57,620 as a function of S_T. 314 00:14:57,620 --> 00:15:00,870 And here are three functions of S_T. [INAUDIBLE] 315 00:15:00,870 --> 00:15:06,320 And then I'm just going to get notation for the price at t 316 00:15:06,320 --> 00:15:08,760 less than or equal to T. We can think about little t 317 00:15:08,760 --> 00:15:10,600 as current time today, or we can think 318 00:15:10,600 --> 00:15:13,460 of some future time between now and capital 319 00:15:13,460 --> 00:15:18,350 T. I'm just going to introduce notation. 320 00:15:18,350 --> 00:15:20,760 Every different finance book uses different notation, so 321 00:15:20,760 --> 00:15:27,990 just C for call price, with strike K, at little t 322 00:15:27,990 --> 00:15:32,100 with maturity big T. OK, just that notation. 323 00:15:32,100 --> 00:15:37,160 The zero-coupon bond-- the price at little t-- 324 00:15:37,160 --> 00:15:39,810 let's call that Z. That's the price of little t. 325 00:15:39,810 --> 00:15:44,110 And the digital-- we'll just call that D. 326 00:15:44,110 --> 00:15:48,042 So this is what we're going to set this up. 327 00:15:48,042 --> 00:15:50,000 Actually, you could have a whole lecture on why 328 00:15:50,000 --> 00:15:51,930 notation-- different notation. 329 00:15:51,930 --> 00:15:54,690 K and capital T are actually embedded 330 00:15:54,690 --> 00:15:56,410 in the terms of the contract. 331 00:15:56,410 --> 00:15:58,050 Little t is in my calendar time. 332 00:15:58,050 --> 00:16:00,350 So you might think why don't you put K and capital 333 00:16:00,350 --> 00:16:01,714 T somewhere else? 334 00:16:01,714 --> 00:16:03,880 Well, when you get actually to modeling derivatives, 335 00:16:03,880 --> 00:16:06,920 you like to be moving both maturity and a forward time 336 00:16:06,920 --> 00:16:07,740 and calendar time. 337 00:16:07,740 --> 00:16:09,281 That's why I just write it like that. 338 00:16:09,281 --> 00:16:12,440 But there's no-- so C sub K, little t, 339 00:16:12,440 --> 00:16:14,380 big T is the price at time of little t 340 00:16:14,380 --> 00:16:19,410 of a call with maturity capital T and strike K. 341 00:16:19,410 --> 00:16:22,100 Black-Scholes and other option pricing formula 342 00:16:22,100 --> 00:16:28,380 are all about determining this-- for t less than T. 343 00:16:28,380 --> 00:16:33,190 Because clearly we know that the price at maturity 344 00:16:33,190 --> 00:16:34,250 is simply the payout. 345 00:16:34,250 --> 00:16:38,200 I mean, that's, again, just the definition. 346 00:16:38,200 --> 00:16:39,130 So that's trivial. 347 00:16:39,130 --> 00:16:43,280 But we want to find out what the price is at little t. 348 00:16:43,280 --> 00:16:45,990 So that's the whole path of finance-- Black-Scholes 349 00:16:45,990 --> 00:16:48,130 and other option pricing methodology 350 00:16:48,130 --> 00:16:49,631 is working out this. 351 00:16:49,631 --> 00:16:51,880 But we're actually going to go down a different route. 352 00:16:54,105 --> 00:16:55,480 So what we're going to do-- we're 353 00:16:55,480 --> 00:16:59,520 going to construct a portfolio. 354 00:16:59,520 --> 00:17:07,020 So consider as a portfolio of what? 355 00:17:07,020 --> 00:17:09,660 We're going to consist of two calls. 356 00:17:09,660 --> 00:17:17,770 OK, we're going to have lambda calls with strike K. OK, 357 00:17:17,770 --> 00:17:19,020 so this is the amount holding. 358 00:17:19,020 --> 00:17:22,119 And everything is going to be with maturity capital T. 359 00:17:22,119 --> 00:17:24,810 So lambda calls with strike K, and maturity T, 360 00:17:24,810 --> 00:17:32,740 and minus lambda calls with strike K plus 1 over lambda. 361 00:17:35,852 --> 00:17:37,310 We'll just consider that portfolio. 362 00:17:37,310 --> 00:17:40,960 It consists of two options. 363 00:17:40,960 --> 00:17:48,620 All right, well, this price at T-- that's easy. 364 00:17:48,620 --> 00:17:54,200 We just write it in terms of lambda 365 00:17:54,200 --> 00:17:57,660 times the price of the call with strike K, 366 00:17:57,660 --> 00:18:06,390 minus lambda call with strike K plus 1 over lambda-- just 367 00:18:06,390 --> 00:18:07,230 by definition. 368 00:18:07,230 --> 00:18:09,920 This is price at T. 369 00:18:09,920 --> 00:18:16,670 OK, well, let's look at its payout at time capital 370 00:18:16,670 --> 00:18:17,495 T graphically. 371 00:18:20,090 --> 00:18:23,250 So we know about call options. 372 00:18:23,250 --> 00:18:27,130 The payout function is just the hockey stick shape, clearly. 373 00:18:27,130 --> 00:18:29,840 That's confusing to people from the UK, because in the UK, 374 00:18:29,840 --> 00:18:32,322 hockey means field hockey, not ice hockey. 375 00:18:32,322 --> 00:18:34,530 And of course, the hockey stick shape in field hockey 376 00:18:34,530 --> 00:18:35,405 looks very different. 377 00:18:35,405 --> 00:18:38,160 Anyway, that's-- you understand what the payout of a call is. 378 00:18:38,160 --> 00:18:40,860 Clearly, this payout function of a call looks like this. 379 00:18:44,910 --> 00:18:51,280 Well, putting this payout of lambda calls 380 00:18:51,280 --> 00:18:53,030 of strike K minus lambda calls of strike K 381 00:18:53,030 --> 00:18:55,105 plus 1 over lambda-- let's assume lambda 382 00:18:55,105 --> 00:18:57,230 is positive for the time being. 383 00:18:57,230 --> 00:18:58,750 What's it look like? 384 00:18:58,750 --> 00:19:06,000 Well, 0 below K, is flat above K plus 1 over lambda. 385 00:19:06,000 --> 00:19:10,820 It has slope lambda, and has value 1 here. 386 00:19:13,730 --> 00:19:18,230 You should be able to see that easily. 387 00:19:18,230 --> 00:19:19,690 So that's the payout. 388 00:19:19,690 --> 00:19:23,670 This is called call spread-- just the spread between two 389 00:19:23,670 --> 00:19:27,390 calls, and has this payout function. 390 00:19:27,390 --> 00:19:30,590 OK, so a natural thing to do here, 391 00:19:30,590 --> 00:19:33,020 it being a mathematics class, let's take limits. 392 00:19:33,020 --> 00:19:34,635 Just let lambda tend to infinity. 393 00:19:41,310 --> 00:19:44,260 Well, then, this becomes the partial derivative 394 00:19:44,260 --> 00:19:48,010 of the call price with respect to K, or the negative of it. 395 00:19:48,010 --> 00:19:49,535 So this tends to minus. 396 00:19:52,700 --> 00:19:59,950 OK, let's just-- so that's that. 397 00:19:59,950 --> 00:20:03,350 And then this, of course as lambda goes to infinity, 398 00:20:03,350 --> 00:20:04,730 this stays at 1. 399 00:20:04,730 --> 00:20:13,510 So this tends to payout function that looks like that. 400 00:20:13,510 --> 00:20:14,010 OK? 401 00:20:16,830 --> 00:20:19,420 This is easy calculus. 402 00:20:19,420 --> 00:20:23,740 This is just by inspection. 403 00:20:23,740 --> 00:20:28,140 OK, so this, clearly, is the payout of the digital. 404 00:20:39,170 --> 00:20:42,120 Of the-- strictly a digital call, 405 00:20:42,120 --> 00:20:44,010 but that's called the digital option. 406 00:20:46,560 --> 00:20:49,190 Just as a note, here it's, just greater than. 407 00:20:49,190 --> 00:20:51,570 You might think, OK, it doesn't matter if it's 408 00:20:51,570 --> 00:20:53,330 greater than or equal to. 409 00:20:53,330 --> 00:20:57,490 Well, in practice, the chance of something equalling a number 410 00:20:57,490 --> 00:21:01,960 exactly is 0-- I mean, if it's a continuous distribution. 411 00:21:01,960 --> 00:21:03,532 In theory, I should say, the chance 412 00:21:03,532 --> 00:21:05,240 of something actually nailing the strike, 413 00:21:05,240 --> 00:21:07,490 actually being equal to K, is 0, so it doesn't really 414 00:21:07,490 --> 00:21:09,750 matter whether you define this as greater than, 415 00:21:09,750 --> 00:21:11,530 or greater than or equal to. 416 00:21:11,530 --> 00:21:14,970 But in practice, of course, finance is in discrete time, 417 00:21:14,970 --> 00:21:17,884 because you don't quote things to a million decimal places. 418 00:21:17,884 --> 00:21:19,300 So certain assets, actually, which 419 00:21:19,300 --> 00:21:23,430 are quoted only in eighths or 16ths or 32nds or 64ths, 420 00:21:23,430 --> 00:21:24,931 this matters, actually, whether it's 421 00:21:24,931 --> 00:21:27,096 defined as greater than or greater than or equal to. 422 00:21:27,096 --> 00:21:29,320 But theoretically, it doesn't make any difference. 423 00:21:29,320 --> 00:21:38,120 OK, so we've got the call spread tending to the digital. 424 00:21:38,120 --> 00:21:46,450 All right, so this tends to-- so the limit of this call 425 00:21:46,450 --> 00:21:52,730 spread-- of this price of the call spread-- is the digital. 426 00:21:52,730 --> 00:22:04,880 And so we know that because this is the price at t. 427 00:22:04,880 --> 00:22:08,670 This is the payout at capital T. The price of the digital 428 00:22:08,670 --> 00:22:11,590 must equal just the partial derivative with respect 429 00:22:11,590 --> 00:22:13,150 to strike of the call price. 430 00:22:16,330 --> 00:22:21,490 So that's just a nice, little result. Where does this 431 00:22:21,490 --> 00:22:24,280 bring in probability? 432 00:22:24,280 --> 00:22:27,520 So this is the next. 433 00:22:27,520 --> 00:22:33,830 OK, so this is where we'll make one assumption. 434 00:22:33,830 --> 00:22:36,520 And it's actually a very important and fundamental 435 00:22:36,520 --> 00:22:37,855 assumption. 436 00:22:37,855 --> 00:22:39,230 And it's fundamental because it's 437 00:22:39,230 --> 00:22:42,080 called The Fundamental Theorem of Finance, 438 00:22:42,080 --> 00:22:46,690 or the Fundamental Theorem of Asset Prices. 439 00:22:46,690 --> 00:22:51,795 So I call this FTAP-- Fundamental Theorem 440 00:22:51,795 --> 00:22:52,503 of Asset Pricing. 441 00:22:56,780 --> 00:22:59,500 By this theorem, which we are going to assume here, 442 00:22:59,500 --> 00:23:06,530 the intuitive answer is correct, meaning that prices today 443 00:23:06,530 --> 00:23:08,290 are expected values. 444 00:23:08,290 --> 00:23:11,580 It's the expectation of a future payout. 445 00:23:11,580 --> 00:23:26,399 So by FTAP, the price at t is expected payout 446 00:23:26,399 --> 00:23:31,365 at time capital T, suitably discounted. 447 00:23:35,250 --> 00:23:40,050 So there's both something very straightforward here, 448 00:23:40,050 --> 00:23:42,130 and something very deep. 449 00:23:42,130 --> 00:23:44,530 If you think about how much would 450 00:23:44,530 --> 00:23:48,700 you pay for a contract that gives you 451 00:23:48,700 --> 00:23:52,940 $1 if an event happens-- in this case, the event being 452 00:23:52,940 --> 00:23:55,850 stock being greater than K at maturity. 453 00:23:55,850 --> 00:23:57,620 You would intuitively think that's related 454 00:23:57,620 --> 00:24:01,270 to the probability of the event happening. 455 00:24:01,270 --> 00:24:03,610 How much will you pay to see the dollar 456 00:24:03,610 --> 00:24:04,660 if a coin comes up heads? 457 00:24:04,660 --> 00:24:09,820 You'd pay a half, probably. 458 00:24:09,820 --> 00:24:11,480 It's very, very intuitive. 459 00:24:11,480 --> 00:24:15,550 But the deepness is, this actually 460 00:24:15,550 --> 00:24:20,370 holds under a particular probability distribution. 461 00:24:20,370 --> 00:24:23,050 I'm not going to go into that here, 462 00:24:23,050 --> 00:24:27,640 but by the fundamental theorem, this is true. 463 00:24:27,640 --> 00:24:30,602 So I can write, in the case of the digital, 464 00:24:30,602 --> 00:24:39,680 the digital price equals the discounted-- 465 00:24:39,680 --> 00:24:43,430 and we'll explain why we want to put the zero-coupon bond 466 00:24:43,430 --> 00:24:48,394 price here-- that's the present value of a dollar at time t. 467 00:24:48,394 --> 00:24:49,560 It's just a discount factor. 468 00:24:49,560 --> 00:24:51,420 It's very trivial, but it's written 469 00:24:51,420 --> 00:24:55,260 in terms of an asset price-- times the expected value 470 00:24:55,260 --> 00:24:57,400 of the payout. 471 00:25:03,700 --> 00:25:11,200 So either you take this as this makes a lot of sense-- 472 00:25:11,200 --> 00:25:14,030 the discounted expected payout-- or you can say, 473 00:25:14,030 --> 00:25:15,030 I don't understand this. 474 00:25:15,030 --> 00:25:17,280 I want to find out about the Fundamental Theorem Asset 475 00:25:17,280 --> 00:25:20,170 Pricing, which we will prove in my class. 476 00:25:20,170 --> 00:25:22,440 But this intuitively makes sense. 477 00:25:22,440 --> 00:25:26,630 The key here is that the expected value actually 478 00:25:26,630 --> 00:25:30,480 has to be taken out under the appropriate distribution, 479 00:25:30,480 --> 00:25:32,320 called the risk-neutral distribution. 480 00:25:32,320 --> 00:25:38,660 But this formula holds-- in fact, strictly. 481 00:25:38,660 --> 00:25:41,730 I'll write this is just for-- what 482 00:25:41,730 --> 00:25:48,400 holds is the price at time little t divided 483 00:25:48,400 --> 00:25:55,130 by zero-coupon bond is a martingale-- for those of you 484 00:25:55,130 --> 00:26:00,112 into probability theory. 485 00:26:00,112 --> 00:26:02,070 This gets probabilists very excited, of course, 486 00:26:02,070 --> 00:26:03,230 because they love martingales. 487 00:26:03,230 --> 00:26:05,490 Everyone in probability theory loves martingales-- lot 488 00:26:05,490 --> 00:26:07,770 of theorems about martingales. 489 00:26:07,770 --> 00:26:12,740 And you'll see, of course that this is actually a restatement 490 00:26:12,740 --> 00:26:18,000 of this assertion. 491 00:26:18,000 --> 00:26:22,080 Because Z, capital T, capital T is 1. 492 00:26:22,080 --> 00:26:26,280 So this statement here is simply a re-expression 493 00:26:26,280 --> 00:26:28,640 of this martingale condition. 494 00:26:28,640 --> 00:26:29,917 So I'll just pause here. 495 00:26:29,917 --> 00:26:31,500 Just from a probability point of view, 496 00:26:31,500 --> 00:26:33,833 when I learned probability, it was under David Williams, 497 00:26:33,833 --> 00:26:36,840 who wrote the book Probability With Martingales, 498 00:26:36,840 --> 00:26:37,930 which is a wonderful book. 499 00:26:37,930 --> 00:26:39,679 And I thought martingale is a great thing. 500 00:26:39,679 --> 00:26:40,810 So I was sort of happy. 501 00:26:40,810 --> 00:26:42,470 It took me about seven or eight years 502 00:26:42,470 --> 00:26:43,982 of being in finance to realize there 503 00:26:43,982 --> 00:26:45,940 are a whole lot of martingales floating around. 504 00:26:45,940 --> 00:26:49,210 Because this actual approach-- this formalization 505 00:26:49,210 --> 00:26:52,930 of asset pricing really only became 506 00:26:52,930 --> 00:26:56,770 embraced on the trade floor around the early 2000's, even 507 00:26:56,770 --> 00:26:59,650 though the underlying theory was always there-- 508 00:26:59,650 --> 00:27:01,450 this idea of these martingales. 509 00:27:01,450 --> 00:27:06,730 Anyway, so this is-- and this, of course, 510 00:27:06,730 --> 00:27:14,225 is simply-- the expected value of the indicator function 511 00:27:14,225 --> 00:27:16,430 is just the probability of the event. 512 00:27:16,430 --> 00:27:17,870 OK. 513 00:27:17,870 --> 00:27:22,810 All right, so now I've won by intuition. 514 00:27:22,810 --> 00:27:26,590 Just here's the probability of the payout occurring. 515 00:27:26,590 --> 00:27:27,937 I've priced the digital. 516 00:27:27,937 --> 00:27:29,520 I've also priced the digital by taking 517 00:27:29,520 --> 00:27:31,389 the limit of call spreads. 518 00:27:31,389 --> 00:27:32,930 So now I'm just going to equate them. 519 00:27:37,200 --> 00:27:41,760 So by equating these two prices for the digital, 520 00:27:41,760 --> 00:27:46,790 I simply get that the derivative of the call price with respect 521 00:27:46,790 --> 00:27:57,410 to strike equals the discounted probability of the stock being 522 00:27:57,410 --> 00:28:02,620 above K. I've just reorganized a little bit, take 1 minus. 523 00:28:02,620 --> 00:28:08,520 So I get the probability that-- well, I can clearly 524 00:28:08,520 --> 00:28:12,320 reorganize again and get-- all right, 525 00:28:12,320 --> 00:28:15,420 so if I want to simply get the cumulative distribution 526 00:28:15,420 --> 00:28:16,840 function, it's just 1 minus this. 527 00:28:16,840 --> 00:28:19,930 So divide here, take 1 minus. 528 00:28:19,930 --> 00:28:22,880 OK, so I get the cumulative distribution function 529 00:28:22,880 --> 00:28:31,000 for the stock price at T is equal to 1 plus dC by dK times 530 00:28:31,000 --> 00:28:35,580 1 over Z. I'm just rearranging. 531 00:28:35,580 --> 00:28:38,200 So here now is the cumulative distribution function. 532 00:28:38,200 --> 00:28:40,440 Clearly, I just need to differentiate again 533 00:28:40,440 --> 00:28:43,670 to get the probability density function. 534 00:28:43,670 --> 00:28:49,687 So here's where the notation gets kind of messy, 535 00:28:49,687 --> 00:28:51,520 but clearly the probability density function 536 00:28:51,520 --> 00:28:59,500 of-- f for my random variable S sub T-- 537 00:28:59,500 --> 00:29:03,452 so the density of-- express that as-- I always-- probabilists, 538 00:29:03,452 --> 00:29:04,910 whenever they talk about densities, 539 00:29:04,910 --> 00:29:06,290 they always want to say f of x. 540 00:29:06,290 --> 00:29:07,010 And it's the same with me. 541 00:29:07,010 --> 00:29:07,600 That's f of x. 542 00:29:07,600 --> 00:29:10,214 Here's the density is simply just the next, 543 00:29:10,214 --> 00:29:11,130 the second derivative. 544 00:29:11,130 --> 00:29:12,700 We'll take the derivative of this. 545 00:29:12,700 --> 00:29:16,130 It's the second derivative of the call price with respect 546 00:29:16,130 --> 00:29:22,570 to strike, evaluated at little x. 547 00:29:22,570 --> 00:29:25,680 All right, so what we've done here 548 00:29:25,680 --> 00:29:29,000 is start off with simple definition 549 00:29:29,000 --> 00:29:32,930 of three assets, price to digital in two different ways. 550 00:29:32,930 --> 00:29:36,720 And now we have a rather elegant linkage 551 00:29:36,720 --> 00:29:43,940 between call prices-- C-- and the density 552 00:29:43,940 --> 00:29:48,790 of the random variable that is the underlying stock 553 00:29:48,790 --> 00:29:54,960 price at capital T. OK, so we've established 554 00:29:54,960 --> 00:30:02,050 one side of the duality, which is given the set of call prices 555 00:30:02,050 --> 00:30:10,720 for all K, I can then uniquely determine the density 556 00:30:10,720 --> 00:30:15,303 of the underlying asset. 557 00:30:20,460 --> 00:30:25,490 So you might think, OK, this is kind of nice. 558 00:30:25,490 --> 00:30:29,430 How does this actually work in practice? 559 00:30:29,430 --> 00:30:33,450 Do we actually think in terms of probability trading? 560 00:30:33,450 --> 00:30:37,600 We just said that call options are equivalent to probability 561 00:30:37,600 --> 00:30:39,140 density functions. 562 00:30:39,140 --> 00:30:41,310 Well, actually, there's a very neat way 563 00:30:41,310 --> 00:30:44,810 of accessing this density function 564 00:30:44,810 --> 00:30:47,380 through another portfolio of options. 565 00:30:47,380 --> 00:30:50,650 OK, so this is actually where we get-- to me 566 00:30:50,650 --> 00:30:53,220 it's the practical relevance of some of this theory. 567 00:30:53,220 --> 00:30:56,306 So let me just show you that. 568 00:30:56,306 --> 00:30:58,180 So we're going to consider another portfolio. 569 00:30:58,180 --> 00:31:06,230 So here we consider portfolio as follows-- 570 00:31:06,230 --> 00:31:09,120 it's actually going to be the difference between two call 571 00:31:09,120 --> 00:31:10,070 spreads. 572 00:31:10,070 --> 00:31:20,990 So lambda calls with strike K minus 1 over lambda. 573 00:31:24,180 --> 00:31:31,340 Minus 2 lambda calls with strike K, 574 00:31:31,340 --> 00:31:38,714 and lambda calls with strike K plus 1 over lambda-- again, 575 00:31:38,714 --> 00:31:39,380 lambda positive. 576 00:31:43,750 --> 00:31:45,670 OK, why are we doing this? 577 00:31:45,670 --> 00:31:47,910 Let's just stop for a bit of intuition. 578 00:31:47,910 --> 00:31:53,180 Here we see in the call spread the discrete approximation 579 00:31:53,180 --> 00:31:58,032 to the first derivative of call price with respect to strike. 580 00:31:58,032 --> 00:31:59,990 So clearly, if I want to approximate the second 581 00:31:59,990 --> 00:32:04,230 derivative, I'm going to take the difference between two call 582 00:32:04,230 --> 00:32:05,835 spreads appropriately scaled. 583 00:32:05,835 --> 00:32:07,960 You're now going to have to have a little-- there's 584 00:32:07,960 --> 00:32:11,590 got to be another lambda coming in here at some point. 585 00:32:11,590 --> 00:32:13,970 This is just the difference between two call spreads, 586 00:32:13,970 --> 00:32:17,590 so that's the difference between two approximations 587 00:32:17,590 --> 00:32:18,590 of the first derivative. 588 00:32:18,590 --> 00:32:21,215 So I'm going to have to scale by lambda in order to approximate 589 00:32:21,215 --> 00:32:22,660 the second derivative. 590 00:32:22,660 --> 00:32:25,070 So this is actually called a call butterfly. 591 00:32:32,304 --> 00:32:34,220 And this is a beautiful thing for two reasons. 592 00:32:34,220 --> 00:32:37,370 One is they actually trade a lot-- surprisingly. 593 00:32:37,370 --> 00:32:39,965 This is not a contrived thing I just made up. 594 00:32:39,965 --> 00:32:42,340 A, it trades a lot, so you can actually trade this thing. 595 00:32:42,340 --> 00:32:46,320 The second is you can kind of imagine 596 00:32:46,320 --> 00:32:49,240 the right scaling of this call butterfly 597 00:32:49,240 --> 00:32:52,450 is going to approximate the second derivative, 598 00:32:52,450 --> 00:32:55,960 and that's approximating the density function. 599 00:32:55,960 --> 00:33:01,611 So this is a traded object that will approximate the density 600 00:33:01,611 --> 00:33:02,110 function. 601 00:33:02,110 --> 00:33:03,194 Yeah, you have a question? 602 00:33:03,194 --> 00:33:04,610 AUDIENCE: Yeah, I have a question. 603 00:33:04,610 --> 00:33:06,370 In the real world, you cannot really-- 604 00:33:06,370 --> 00:33:10,130 the strike distance cannot really go to infinitely small, 605 00:33:10,130 --> 00:33:12,745 so they have some [INAUDIBLE] way how to approximate that? 606 00:33:12,745 --> 00:33:14,680 STEPHEN BLYTHE: Yeah, so that's a good point. 607 00:33:14,680 --> 00:33:16,860 Yeah, so the question is how, in practice, we 608 00:33:16,860 --> 00:33:18,690 can't go infinitely small, which is true. 609 00:33:18,690 --> 00:33:21,460 But we can go pretty small. 610 00:33:21,460 --> 00:33:24,860 So in interest rates, we might be 611 00:33:24,860 --> 00:33:31,820 able to trade a 150, 160, 170 call 612 00:33:31,820 --> 00:33:34,640 butterfly or equivalent-- 10 basis points wide. 613 00:33:34,640 --> 00:33:37,350 That's a-- it's a reasonable approximation 614 00:33:37,350 --> 00:33:40,330 to the probability of being in that interval. 615 00:33:40,330 --> 00:33:42,870 So these are all, I mean, you make a good point. 616 00:33:42,870 --> 00:33:44,950 In fact, all of finance is discrete, in my view. 617 00:33:44,950 --> 00:33:48,010 So continuous-time finance is done in continuous time 618 00:33:48,010 --> 00:33:50,600 because the theory is much more elegant. 619 00:33:50,600 --> 00:33:54,540 But in practice, it's discrete in time and space. 620 00:33:54,540 --> 00:33:59,370 You can only trade finitely often in a day, and so on. 621 00:33:59,370 --> 00:34:01,865 I won't going into the detail, but you can see the price. 622 00:34:01,865 --> 00:34:03,240 Let me just write down the first. 623 00:34:03,240 --> 00:34:07,090 The price of this I have just expressed as the difference 624 00:34:07,090 --> 00:34:09,550 between two call spreads. 625 00:34:09,550 --> 00:34:15,710 So it's lambda times the call spread from 1 minus lambda 626 00:34:15,710 --> 00:34:30,010 to K, so K, 1 minus lambda to K, minus the call spread 627 00:34:30,010 --> 00:34:34,020 from K to K plus 1 over lambda. 628 00:34:39,380 --> 00:34:41,020 OK, so the difference between two call 629 00:34:41,020 --> 00:34:46,638 spreads-- we'll call this-- this is the butterfly. 630 00:34:46,638 --> 00:34:48,429 We're just going to use temporary notation, 631 00:34:48,429 --> 00:34:52,469 call that B, B for butterfly. 632 00:34:52,469 --> 00:34:54,795 So the price B, and then you get confused. 633 00:34:54,795 --> 00:34:58,812 It's B centered at K with width lambda. 634 00:34:58,812 --> 00:35:00,770 No one ever uses this notation outside this one 635 00:35:00,770 --> 00:35:02,300 section of my class, so that's why, 636 00:35:02,300 --> 00:35:04,120 but it's just handy for this. 637 00:35:04,120 --> 00:35:06,487 So that is-- the butterfly price is 638 00:35:06,487 --> 00:35:08,570 equal to the difference in these two call spreads. 639 00:35:08,570 --> 00:35:10,150 What I want to do is, I want to take 640 00:35:10,150 --> 00:35:12,930 limits of this, suitably scaled, to get the second derivative. 641 00:35:12,930 --> 00:35:22,220 And if you just take lambda times B_K of lambda, 642 00:35:22,220 --> 00:35:25,810 t, T is indeed, approximately-- if I 643 00:35:25,810 --> 00:35:31,725 take limits is exactly-- the second derivative of call 644 00:35:31,725 --> 00:35:32,225 price. 645 00:35:35,440 --> 00:35:39,630 OK, so here's how I'm accessing the second derivative 646 00:35:39,630 --> 00:35:41,911 through a portfolio of traded options. 647 00:35:41,911 --> 00:35:42,410 All right? 648 00:35:42,410 --> 00:35:46,820 And so the price of this butterfly, B, 649 00:35:46,820 --> 00:35:51,960 if I just reorganize and substitute-- so I get 650 00:35:51,960 --> 00:35:58,560 B_K-- for large lambda, i.e. 651 00:35:58,560 --> 00:36:03,180 a small interval-- is approximately 1 652 00:36:03,180 --> 00:36:09,950 over lambda times the density function-- actually, 653 00:36:09,950 --> 00:36:22,130 evaluated at K. So I have obtained this density function 654 00:36:22,130 --> 00:36:23,410 by this traded portfolio. 655 00:36:23,410 --> 00:36:26,451 And to your point about we're not getting infinitely small. 656 00:36:26,451 --> 00:36:27,450 That's absolutely right. 657 00:36:27,450 --> 00:36:29,366 But if you think about what the density-- when 658 00:36:29,366 --> 00:36:33,450 you learn about density functions for the first time, 659 00:36:33,450 --> 00:36:36,430 you say the density function at x times a small interval 660 00:36:36,430 --> 00:36:38,650 is the probability of being in that small interval. 661 00:36:38,650 --> 00:36:41,700 All right, so when we think about the density 662 00:36:41,700 --> 00:36:50,370 function f of x, if you have a small interval of delta x, 663 00:36:50,370 --> 00:36:54,030 then clearly the probability of being in this interval 664 00:36:54,030 --> 00:36:59,020 is approximately f of x, delta x. 665 00:36:59,020 --> 00:37:00,349 In the limit, that is true. 666 00:37:00,349 --> 00:37:02,140 So what we're showing here, if you actually 667 00:37:02,140 --> 00:37:04,237 think about what interval we're looking at, 668 00:37:04,237 --> 00:37:06,320 we're actually looking at in this call butterfly-- 669 00:37:06,320 --> 00:37:08,340 if you were actually to draw it out, 670 00:37:08,340 --> 00:37:17,430 this call butterfly looks like that around K. 671 00:37:17,430 --> 00:37:19,060 It actually-- it's a little triangle. 672 00:37:19,060 --> 00:37:21,434 It's not actually a rectangle, but it's a little triangle 673 00:37:21,434 --> 00:37:23,550 of width 2 over lambda. 674 00:37:23,550 --> 00:37:31,490 OK, so it is actually-- this is the area of this triangle-- 675 00:37:31,490 --> 00:37:33,870 2 over lambda times 1/2 times f of x. 676 00:37:33,870 --> 00:37:36,150 And that's actually this, right? 677 00:37:36,150 --> 00:37:41,700 So this has width 2 over lambda. 678 00:37:41,700 --> 00:37:43,710 OK, so in fact, we've got here exactly 679 00:37:43,710 --> 00:37:45,600 an approximate-- exactly approximation, 680 00:37:45,600 --> 00:37:46,780 that doesn't sound right. 681 00:37:46,780 --> 00:37:50,020 But it's entirely analogous to the approximation 682 00:37:50,020 --> 00:37:52,110 of the probability of being a small interval. 683 00:37:52,110 --> 00:37:57,640 Here is the probability of being in this interval 684 00:37:57,640 --> 00:38:04,900 here-- just the area under that is exactly 685 00:38:04,900 --> 00:38:06,230 1 over lambda f of x. 686 00:38:06,230 --> 00:38:09,890 So here is actually something that people do do, is they say, 687 00:38:09,890 --> 00:38:16,380 OK, I will look at the price of this butterfly, which gives me 688 00:38:16,380 --> 00:38:19,010 the probability of this underlying 689 00:38:19,010 --> 00:38:23,270 random variable ending up around K. 690 00:38:23,270 --> 00:38:26,850 I'll make a judgment whether I agree with that probability 691 00:38:26,850 --> 00:38:28,620 or not. 692 00:38:28,620 --> 00:38:32,300 And if I think that probability is higher 693 00:38:32,300 --> 00:38:38,260 than this price implies, then I'll do a trade. 694 00:38:38,260 --> 00:38:39,030 I'll buy it. 695 00:38:39,030 --> 00:38:41,990 I'll buy that butterfly. 696 00:38:41,990 --> 00:38:48,122 So there is actually an active market in butterflies, 697 00:38:48,122 --> 00:38:49,580 and so I think an active trading in 698 00:38:49,580 --> 00:38:54,340 probabilities-- probabilities of the underlying variable being 699 00:38:54,340 --> 00:38:56,700 at K at maturity. 700 00:38:59,250 --> 00:39:03,770 So OK, so that's the first linkage here. 701 00:39:03,770 --> 00:39:06,280 Both-- the density is the second derivative, 702 00:39:06,280 --> 00:39:08,080 and the second derivative is essentially 703 00:39:08,080 --> 00:39:09,790 a portfolio of traded options. 704 00:39:09,790 --> 00:39:15,822 And none of this is dependent on the actual price of the call 705 00:39:15,822 --> 00:39:18,231 option, in the sense that this holds regardless. 706 00:39:18,231 --> 00:39:20,730 Clearly, this is a function of the price of the call option, 707 00:39:20,730 --> 00:39:24,660 but I don't need any model for the option price 708 00:39:24,660 --> 00:39:27,850 to hold, in order for these relationships to hold. 709 00:39:27,850 --> 00:39:31,350 So these are model-independent relationships, clearly. 710 00:39:31,350 --> 00:39:39,130 If you were to put the Black-Scholes formula into C-- 711 00:39:39,130 --> 00:39:41,140 Black-Scholes formula of the call price-- 712 00:39:41,140 --> 00:39:44,420 and take the second derivative with respect to K, which 713 00:39:44,420 --> 00:39:49,115 would be a mess, you'll end up with a log-normal distribution. 714 00:39:49,115 --> 00:39:51,365 Because that's what actually the Black-Scholes formula 715 00:39:51,365 --> 00:39:52,823 is, is expected value of the payout 716 00:39:52,823 --> 00:39:54,320 under a log-normal distribution. 717 00:39:54,320 --> 00:39:55,660 And that will hold. 718 00:39:55,660 --> 00:39:57,226 So this will hold for that. 719 00:39:57,226 --> 00:39:59,100 AUDIENCE: [INAUDIBLE]? 720 00:39:59,100 --> 00:40:01,184 STEPHEN BLYTHE: Yes. 721 00:40:01,184 --> 00:40:03,184 AUDIENCE: The last [INAUDIBLE] So left-hand side 722 00:40:03,184 --> 00:40:06,470 depends on the small t. 723 00:40:06,470 --> 00:40:07,964 STEPHEN BLYTHE: Yes, it does. 724 00:40:07,964 --> 00:40:08,880 AUDIENCE: But the right-hand side does not. 725 00:40:08,880 --> 00:40:09,900 What's the role of that? 726 00:40:09,900 --> 00:40:11,941 STEPHEN BLYTHE: Yeah, that's a really good point. 727 00:40:11,941 --> 00:40:13,250 I've been loose in my notation. 728 00:40:13,250 --> 00:40:15,050 So here what is it? 729 00:40:15,050 --> 00:40:17,540 It's actually the conditional distribution of S capital 730 00:40:17,540 --> 00:40:19,780 T, given S little t. 731 00:40:19,780 --> 00:40:22,510 So this is the conditional distribution, 732 00:40:22,510 --> 00:40:25,810 given that we're currently at time little t with price S 733 00:40:25,810 --> 00:40:29,930 little t for the distribution at time capital T. 734 00:40:29,930 --> 00:40:31,110 So that's where it comes in. 735 00:40:31,110 --> 00:40:32,110 That's absolutely right. 736 00:40:32,110 --> 00:40:37,540 So in fact, this expected value strictly 737 00:40:37,540 --> 00:40:42,190 should be conditional on S_t. 738 00:40:42,190 --> 00:40:44,300 This probability is a probability 739 00:40:44,300 --> 00:40:48,070 conditional on S_t-- absolutely. 740 00:40:48,070 --> 00:40:50,610 And in fact, this martingale condition 741 00:40:50,610 --> 00:40:56,840 is-- the martingales with respect to S_t. 742 00:40:56,840 --> 00:40:58,782 So that's where the little t comes in. 743 00:40:58,782 --> 00:40:59,698 AUDIENCE: [INAUDIBLE]? 744 00:41:04,900 --> 00:41:06,730 STEPHEN BLYTHE: Here, yes, sorry. 745 00:41:06,730 --> 00:41:11,740 That's 1 over Z. So it's just a constant here. 746 00:41:11,740 --> 00:41:14,520 This number, especially because interest rates 747 00:41:14,520 --> 00:41:18,474 are so low in US, so this number is so close to 1 748 00:41:18,474 --> 00:41:19,890 that you always forget about that. 749 00:41:19,890 --> 00:41:22,320 Not when we're trading, but when you, oh well, this 750 00:41:22,320 --> 00:41:26,870 is just a-- if you just think about which one is-- this 751 00:41:26,870 --> 00:41:29,570 is a quantity that's in the future. 752 00:41:29,570 --> 00:41:34,460 It's call prices, so that's how you kind of go. 753 00:41:34,460 --> 00:41:37,870 All right, so that's the first bit. 754 00:41:41,320 --> 00:41:44,890 So when I was an undergraduate, actually, learning probability, 755 00:41:44,890 --> 00:41:47,190 one thing I learned about probability 756 00:41:47,190 --> 00:41:49,940 was from my probability lecturer, who said, 757 00:41:49,940 --> 00:41:53,010 the attention span of students is no more than about 758 00:41:53,010 --> 00:41:53,820 40 minutes. 759 00:41:53,820 --> 00:41:56,780 So there's no point lecturing continuously for 40 minutes, 760 00:41:56,780 --> 00:42:00,110 because people will just start switching off after 40 minutes. 761 00:42:00,110 --> 00:42:03,125 So rather than wait, just have a break and waste the time, 762 00:42:03,125 --> 00:42:04,500 the lecturer said, I'm just going 763 00:42:04,500 --> 00:42:06,510 to give you some random information in the break, 764 00:42:06,510 --> 00:42:08,120 and then we'll go back to probability. 765 00:42:08,120 --> 00:42:10,014 So I learned that from 25 years ago. 766 00:42:10,014 --> 00:42:12,180 I can't remember-- I actually remember the material. 767 00:42:12,180 --> 00:42:13,450 I can't remember any of the random material. 768 00:42:13,450 --> 00:42:14,908 So that's what I do in my lectures, 769 00:42:14,908 --> 00:42:17,290 is I break them up, and talk about something random. 770 00:42:17,290 --> 00:42:19,680 So I thought I'd do that here as well, with some-- 771 00:42:19,680 --> 00:42:21,090 not completely random. 772 00:42:21,090 --> 00:42:23,740 So this is somewhat applicable, this being a math class. 773 00:42:23,740 --> 00:42:28,547 So how many of you are math concentrators or applied math 774 00:42:28,547 --> 00:42:29,130 concentrators? 775 00:42:29,130 --> 00:42:31,930 One, two-- a lot, applied math concentrators-- 776 00:42:31,930 --> 00:42:36,424 especially for the applied math concentrators, 777 00:42:36,424 --> 00:42:37,840 going straight to the conclusion-- 778 00:42:37,840 --> 00:42:39,270 your entire syllabus was generated 779 00:42:39,270 --> 00:42:40,270 at Cambridge University. 780 00:42:40,270 --> 00:42:41,520 That's the conclusion. 781 00:42:41,520 --> 00:42:43,450 So anyway, here's the story. 782 00:42:43,450 --> 00:42:49,670 So back in the 19th century, the Cambridge Mathematics degree-- 783 00:42:49,670 --> 00:42:51,810 the undergraduate Mathematics degree-- 784 00:42:51,810 --> 00:42:55,430 was the most prestigious degree in the world. 785 00:42:55,430 --> 00:42:59,130 In fact, it was actually the first undergraduate degree 786 00:42:59,130 --> 00:43:02,350 with a written examination was Cambridge Mathematics. 787 00:43:02,350 --> 00:43:06,190 So they have a lot to be responsible for. 788 00:43:06,190 --> 00:43:09,770 And each year, people took the exam. 789 00:43:09,770 --> 00:43:11,640 And they were ranked. 790 00:43:11,640 --> 00:43:14,850 And that ranking was published in the Times of London-- 791 00:43:14,850 --> 00:43:16,207 so the national newspaper. 792 00:43:16,207 --> 00:43:18,040 And the people who got first-class degrees-- 793 00:43:18,040 --> 00:43:20,950 so summa degrees-- in Cambridge Mathematics 794 00:43:20,950 --> 00:43:23,920 were called wranglers, and still are called wranglers, actually. 795 00:43:23,920 --> 00:43:25,545 And the reason they're called wranglers 796 00:43:25,545 --> 00:43:27,770 was from way back in the 17th century 797 00:43:27,770 --> 00:43:29,937 where, before they had exams-- or 18th century, 798 00:43:29,937 --> 00:43:32,620 I should say, before they had exams-- instead of writing down 799 00:43:32,620 --> 00:43:34,350 exam, you have to argue, or dispute, 800 00:43:34,350 --> 00:43:38,020 or wrangle with your professor to get to pass the class. 801 00:43:38,020 --> 00:43:39,800 So that's where wrangler comes from. 802 00:43:39,800 --> 00:43:42,822 So these people who got the first-class degree 803 00:43:42,822 --> 00:43:44,530 are called wranglers, and they're ranked. 804 00:43:44,530 --> 00:43:46,390 And basically, the senior wrangler 805 00:43:46,390 --> 00:43:50,420 was a very famous person in the UK in the 19th century. 806 00:43:50,420 --> 00:43:53,410 And a lot of them turned out to be quite successful. 807 00:43:53,410 --> 00:43:55,900 So here are a few wranglers. 808 00:43:55,900 --> 00:44:01,180 I've just got this one-- I can't reach that, but [INAUDIBLE]. 809 00:44:01,180 --> 00:44:04,400 So some of you might recognize-- and I just 810 00:44:04,400 --> 00:44:07,680 want to tell you a quick story about one of them. 811 00:44:12,290 --> 00:44:18,210 OK, so let's start 1841, senior wrangler 812 00:44:18,210 --> 00:44:22,690 was George Stokes-- so basic fluid dynamics-- 813 00:44:22,690 --> 00:44:25,094 the whole of fluid dynamics-- that's George Stokes. 814 00:44:31,216 --> 00:44:32,986 1854, second wrangler-- this is-- 815 00:44:32,986 --> 00:44:34,110 who was the first wrangler? 816 00:44:34,110 --> 00:44:37,670 The second wrangler was James Maxwell, so electrodynamics, 817 00:44:37,670 --> 00:44:39,195 Maxwell equations. 818 00:44:39,195 --> 00:44:39,945 He was the second. 819 00:44:39,945 --> 00:44:44,090 And I can't quite work out who was the first. 820 00:44:44,090 --> 00:44:50,450 1880, the second wrangler was J.J. Thompson, so electrons, 821 00:44:50,450 --> 00:44:55,190 atomic physics, that comes out of-- he was only second. 822 00:44:55,190 --> 00:44:57,890 1865, senior wrangler Lord Rayleigh. 823 00:44:57,890 --> 00:45:00,350 So he was the sky is blue. 824 00:45:03,322 --> 00:45:05,090 He was first. 825 00:45:05,090 --> 00:45:08,570 So they're a pretty good bunch. 826 00:45:08,570 --> 00:45:12,290 So the story-- the best of 1845-- 827 00:45:12,290 --> 00:45:14,920 I'm going back-- the second wrangler 828 00:45:14,920 --> 00:45:18,971 was Lord Kelvin, so absolute zero, amongst other things, 829 00:45:18,971 --> 00:45:19,470 of course. 830 00:45:19,470 --> 00:45:21,900 But absolute zero-- he was second wrangler. 831 00:45:21,900 --> 00:45:23,930 And the great story about him, he 832 00:45:23,930 --> 00:45:26,020 was the most talented mathematician of his-- 833 00:45:26,020 --> 00:45:28,040 of the decade. 834 00:45:28,040 --> 00:45:30,030 And he was such a lock for senior wrangler 835 00:45:30,030 --> 00:45:31,755 that-- and I actually read the biography, 836 00:45:31,755 --> 00:45:34,390 so this is a sort of true statement-- 837 00:45:34,390 --> 00:45:37,800 that he sent his servant to the Senate House where 838 00:45:37,800 --> 00:45:40,680 these things are being read out, and with a request, "Tell me 839 00:45:40,680 --> 00:45:42,120 who is second wrangler." 840 00:45:42,120 --> 00:45:44,720 And the servant came back, and said, you, sir. 841 00:45:44,720 --> 00:45:49,150 And because he was such a lock to be first wrangler. 842 00:45:49,150 --> 00:45:51,370 And in fact, what happened was a question 843 00:45:51,370 --> 00:45:55,880 on the mathematical exam was a theorem 844 00:45:55,880 --> 00:45:58,440 that he had proved two years before in the Cambridge 845 00:45:58,440 --> 00:46:00,730 Mathematical Journal. 846 00:46:00,730 --> 00:46:02,570 So his theorem was set on the exam. 847 00:46:02,570 --> 00:46:05,040 Because he had not memorized it, so he 848 00:46:05,040 --> 00:46:07,890 had to reprove it, whereas the person who 849 00:46:07,890 --> 00:46:10,610 became senior wrangler had memorized the proof, 850 00:46:10,610 --> 00:46:11,860 and was able to regenerate it. 851 00:46:11,860 --> 00:46:13,609 In those days, there was a lot of cramming 852 00:46:13,609 --> 00:46:14,850 to be done in these exams. 853 00:46:14,850 --> 00:46:18,250 So the guy who-- Stephen Parkinson was senior wrangler. 854 00:46:18,250 --> 00:46:19,870 He went on to be FRS, and eminent. 855 00:46:19,870 --> 00:46:24,350 But he wasn't-- so anyway, so here's the applied math 856 00:46:24,350 --> 00:46:25,477 syllabus. 857 00:46:25,477 --> 00:46:27,560 Here's a couple of other ones which I really like. 858 00:46:27,560 --> 00:46:35,090 In 1904, John Maynard Keynes was at 12th wrangler. 859 00:46:35,090 --> 00:46:37,181 Now, I can tell the story either way, 860 00:46:37,181 --> 00:46:39,430 depending on whether I'm in an audience of economists, 861 00:46:39,430 --> 00:46:40,804 or an audience of mathematicians. 862 00:46:40,804 --> 00:46:43,120 Since I'm in an audience of mathematicians, 863 00:46:43,120 --> 00:46:45,500 I like to say the greatest economist was 864 00:46:45,500 --> 00:46:48,190 so poor at mathematics, he only managed to be 12th wrangler. 865 00:46:48,190 --> 00:46:49,770 There are 11 better mathematicians 866 00:46:49,770 --> 00:46:52,380 in the UK in that year. 867 00:46:52,380 --> 00:46:54,587 So he was obviously not that great. 868 00:46:54,587 --> 00:46:56,420 If I was talking to economists, I would say, 869 00:46:56,420 --> 00:46:59,050 this guy is so brilliant that his main field was economics, 870 00:46:59,050 --> 00:47:02,540 and yet as part time, he's able to be the 12th best 871 00:47:02,540 --> 00:47:04,050 mathematician in the UK. 872 00:47:04,050 --> 00:47:11,860 So last one I wanted to talk about-- 1879-- here's a quiz. 873 00:47:11,860 --> 00:47:13,900 This one you have to have some answers for. 874 00:47:13,900 --> 00:47:21,180 OK, so 1980 something-- I can't remember what it is-- so here's 875 00:47:21,180 --> 00:47:24,880 one, here's two, here's three. 876 00:47:24,880 --> 00:47:26,420 I'm going to give you one and two. 877 00:47:26,420 --> 00:47:27,615 You've got to fill in three. 878 00:47:27,615 --> 00:47:29,990 You probably aren't going to be able to get this one yet, 879 00:47:29,990 --> 00:47:37,100 but this is-- Andrew Alan, senior wrangler, George Walker, 880 00:47:37,100 --> 00:47:43,090 second wrangler, and number three is the question. 881 00:47:43,090 --> 00:47:56,050 That's the question-- 1980, Hakeem Olajuwon, Sam Bowie, 882 00:47:56,050 --> 00:47:57,620 question mark-- who's question mark? 883 00:48:00,780 --> 00:48:03,350 Do we know which sport these people play? 884 00:48:03,350 --> 00:48:04,850 AUDIENCE: That one's Michael Jordan. 885 00:48:04,850 --> 00:48:05,974 STEPHEN BLYTHE: Yes, right. 886 00:48:05,974 --> 00:48:09,490 There we go, that's Michael Jordan-- exactly. 887 00:48:09,490 --> 00:48:12,000 This question could go on forever in the UK because they 888 00:48:12,000 --> 00:48:13,900 don't-- so Michael Jordan, famously, 889 00:48:13,900 --> 00:48:17,370 was only picked third in the NBA draft in 1984, was that-- 890 00:48:17,370 --> 00:48:19,497 four or five, something like that. 891 00:48:19,497 --> 00:48:21,330 So Hakeem Olajuwon was actually pretty good, 892 00:48:21,330 --> 00:48:23,780 but Sam Bowie was a total bust. 893 00:48:23,780 --> 00:48:25,290 But he was third. 894 00:48:25,290 --> 00:48:28,700 So in 1879, in the Cambridge Mathematics Tripos, 895 00:48:28,700 --> 00:48:32,250 these two people you never heard of, who were first and second. 896 00:48:32,250 --> 00:48:35,550 And the person who came third, you've probably heard of him. 897 00:48:35,550 --> 00:48:39,940 This is more of a statistics thing. 898 00:48:39,940 --> 00:48:41,974 People know about correlation? 899 00:48:41,974 --> 00:48:43,890 What's the correlation-- who's the correlation 900 00:48:43,890 --> 00:48:46,065 coefficient named after? 901 00:48:46,065 --> 00:48:46,815 AUDIENCE: Pearson. 902 00:48:46,815 --> 00:48:48,856 STEPHEN BLYTHE: Pearson, you've got Karl Pearson. 903 00:48:48,856 --> 00:48:53,584 So Karl Pearson was the third wrangler in 1879. 904 00:48:53,584 --> 00:48:55,000 And the founder of statistics-- he 905 00:48:55,000 --> 00:48:56,874 founded the first ever statistics department, 906 00:48:56,874 --> 00:48:59,140 and obviously invented correlation 907 00:48:59,140 --> 00:49:00,786 with Gould-- Gould and Pearson. 908 00:49:00,786 --> 00:49:02,410 Anyway, he was only the third wrangler. 909 00:49:02,410 --> 00:49:05,600 And unfortunately, these people have very common names, 910 00:49:05,600 --> 00:49:07,920 so I have no idea what they went on to do. 911 00:49:07,920 --> 00:49:11,170 To Google these people is not very effective. 912 00:49:11,170 --> 00:49:16,090 Anyway, so that's the story of Cambridge Mathematics-- 913 00:49:16,090 --> 00:49:18,860 lots of good stuff. 914 00:49:28,400 --> 00:49:31,310 All right, so in the last half hour, 915 00:49:31,310 --> 00:49:41,160 I just want to go the other way from-- so the other way-- 916 00:49:41,160 --> 00:49:44,020 we went from option prices to probability. 917 00:49:44,020 --> 00:49:45,970 Let's go from probability to option price. 918 00:49:45,970 --> 00:49:47,510 We sort of already have, actually. 919 00:49:47,510 --> 00:49:49,500 This is what the Fundamental Theorem does. 920 00:49:49,500 --> 00:49:51,770 If we're thinking-- if we take on trust 921 00:49:51,770 --> 00:49:53,230 that the Fundamental Theorem holds, 922 00:49:53,230 --> 00:49:58,402 namely option prices today are the discounted expected payout 923 00:49:58,402 --> 00:49:59,940 at maturity. 924 00:49:59,940 --> 00:50:01,450 OK, let's take that on trust. 925 00:50:01,450 --> 00:50:03,690 Then we're going from probability distribution 926 00:50:03,690 --> 00:50:05,231 to option price in the following way. 927 00:50:05,231 --> 00:50:08,730 So let's actually state the Fundamental Theorem, FTAP. 928 00:50:11,630 --> 00:50:17,800 OK, so I'm going to go general derivative D 929 00:50:17,800 --> 00:50:19,820 is-- D, digital D, derivative. 930 00:50:19,820 --> 00:50:35,190 It's-- so derivative with payout at T. 931 00:50:35,190 --> 00:50:36,950 So this could be the digital payout. 932 00:50:36,950 --> 00:50:38,241 It could be call option payout. 933 00:50:38,241 --> 00:50:40,880 It could be one. 934 00:50:40,880 --> 00:50:50,190 And price-- OK, so often, we actually 935 00:50:50,190 --> 00:50:52,850 think about payout function as just a simple function 936 00:50:52,850 --> 00:50:55,870 of the stock price. 937 00:50:55,870 --> 00:50:58,765 But this notation is useful when we think about the price 938 00:50:58,765 --> 00:51:01,170 as being martingales. 939 00:51:01,170 --> 00:51:05,040 Then what is FTAP? 940 00:51:05,040 --> 00:51:13,270 D-- the ratio of the price to the zero coupon bond 941 00:51:13,270 --> 00:51:15,000 is equal to-- is a martingale. 942 00:51:15,000 --> 00:51:17,210 In other words, its expected value 943 00:51:17,210 --> 00:51:20,880 under the special distribution, risk-neutral distribution, 944 00:51:20,880 --> 00:51:22,860 of the payout at maturity. 945 00:51:27,110 --> 00:51:29,680 And to you point, it's conditional on S_t. 946 00:51:29,680 --> 00:51:32,120 So this is the proper statement. 947 00:51:32,120 --> 00:51:34,460 So this is the Fundamental Theorem of Asset Prices. 948 00:51:34,460 --> 00:51:37,080 In words, it's saying this ratio is 949 00:51:37,080 --> 00:51:39,510 a martingale with respect to the stock 950 00:51:39,510 --> 00:51:41,980 price under the risk-neutral distribution. 951 00:51:45,020 --> 00:51:47,670 That's the statement of the Fundamental Theorem. 952 00:51:47,670 --> 00:51:52,600 This is actually rather neat to prove in the binomial tree, 953 00:51:52,600 --> 00:51:54,460 two-state world. 954 00:51:54,460 --> 00:51:57,920 It's very, very difficult to prove in continuous time. 955 00:51:57,920 --> 00:52:01,270 This is Harrison and Kreps in 1979. 956 00:52:01,270 --> 00:52:04,250 It's the proof that, however many times you look at it, 957 00:52:04,250 --> 00:52:06,010 you're only probably going to get through two or three pages 958 00:52:06,010 --> 00:52:07,390 before thinking, OK, that's hard. 959 00:52:07,390 --> 00:52:09,390 But it was done. 960 00:52:09,390 --> 00:52:12,160 So this is, you can imagine continuous time, 961 00:52:12,160 --> 00:52:16,740 infinite amount of trading, infinite states of the world. 962 00:52:16,740 --> 00:52:18,130 OK, so now this, of course, is 1. 963 00:52:21,196 --> 00:52:22,070 And this can come up. 964 00:52:22,070 --> 00:52:23,620 These are known at time little t. 965 00:52:23,620 --> 00:52:26,270 So if I'm thinking at-- if I'm at current time little t, 966 00:52:26,270 --> 00:52:30,150 therefore, the derivative price is 967 00:52:30,150 --> 00:52:33,490 what we had before-- the expected payout. 968 00:52:39,130 --> 00:52:41,430 OK, so this is rather a nice expression. 969 00:52:41,430 --> 00:52:44,541 And now we can actually just write down what this is. 970 00:52:44,541 --> 00:52:50,500 This is the expected value of a function of a random variable. 971 00:52:50,500 --> 00:52:56,305 So this is just the integral of g 972 00:52:56,305 --> 00:53:03,030 of x, f of x, dx, where this is the density 973 00:53:03,030 --> 00:53:06,030 of the random variable at time capital T, 974 00:53:06,030 --> 00:53:07,630 conditional on being at S_t. 975 00:53:07,630 --> 00:53:09,970 So this is conditional at S_t. 976 00:53:09,970 --> 00:53:14,452 So this is a restatement of the Fundamental Theorem. 977 00:53:14,452 --> 00:53:16,410 So this is essentially the Fundamental Theorem. 978 00:53:16,410 --> 00:53:19,080 And this is a intuition made good, 979 00:53:19,080 --> 00:53:21,515 or intuition made real-- expected payouts. 980 00:53:24,580 --> 00:53:26,497 This is sometimes called LOTUS-- the lure 981 00:53:26,497 --> 00:53:27,830 of the unconscious statistician. 982 00:53:27,830 --> 00:53:33,010 Just the expected value of g of x is integral g of x, f of x. 983 00:53:33,010 --> 00:53:35,890 That's not immediate from the definition of expected value. 984 00:53:35,890 --> 00:53:40,350 You should really work out the density of g of x. 985 00:53:40,350 --> 00:53:44,020 And then integral of x-- the density of g of x dx, 986 00:53:44,020 --> 00:53:45,780 but it turns out to be this. 987 00:53:45,780 --> 00:53:47,820 So that's a very nice, nice result. 988 00:53:47,820 --> 00:53:54,240 OK, so here is now a way of going from density to price. 989 00:53:54,240 --> 00:53:58,376 If I put in the call option payout for g, 990 00:53:58,376 --> 00:54:03,350 and I have the density, I can then derive the price C. 991 00:54:03,350 --> 00:54:09,170 So If you like, the way I go from density to probability 992 00:54:09,170 --> 00:54:11,600 distribution to option price is exactly 993 00:54:11,600 --> 00:54:12,990 the Fundamental Theorem. 994 00:54:12,990 --> 00:54:15,682 The route I take is the Fundamental Theorem. 995 00:54:23,720 --> 00:54:27,880 OK, so FTAP, the Fundamental Theorem of Asset Pricing, 996 00:54:27,880 --> 00:54:31,230 means I can going from the probability density 997 00:54:31,230 --> 00:54:37,930 to the price of a derivative, for any derivative. 998 00:54:37,930 --> 00:54:43,000 All right, OK, so now we can go either way-- density 999 00:54:43,000 --> 00:54:48,712 to derivative or call price to density. 1000 00:54:48,712 --> 00:54:49,920 You might say, hang on a sec. 1001 00:54:49,920 --> 00:54:51,560 We've only gone from-- we need the call 1002 00:54:51,560 --> 00:54:53,810 prices to get the density. 1003 00:54:53,810 --> 00:54:59,480 Well, of course, we can go via an intermediate step. 1004 00:54:59,480 --> 00:55:02,920 So to get from the call price to an arbitrary derivative price, 1005 00:55:02,920 --> 00:55:06,450 I just go via the density. 1006 00:55:06,450 --> 00:55:14,520 So in particular-- this is restating-- knowledge 1007 00:55:14,520 --> 00:55:26,710 of all the call prices for all K determines 1008 00:55:26,710 --> 00:55:29,580 this derivative payout for any g. 1009 00:55:33,310 --> 00:55:35,726 So if I know all calls, I know the density. 1010 00:55:35,726 --> 00:55:37,100 And then if I know the density, I 1011 00:55:37,100 --> 00:55:39,090 know an arbitrary derivative price. 1012 00:55:39,090 --> 00:55:41,040 It's obvious as we stated here. 1013 00:55:41,040 --> 00:55:44,095 But what this is saying is, the call options often 1014 00:55:44,095 --> 00:55:46,890 are introduced as this-- why are they important-- 1015 00:55:46,890 --> 00:55:50,620 are the spanning set of all derivative prices. 1016 00:55:50,620 --> 00:56:02,479 So calls span-- call prices span all derivative prices. 1017 00:56:02,479 --> 00:56:04,770 And they are a particular type of derivative-- the ones 1018 00:56:04,770 --> 00:56:09,355 that are determined exactly by their payout at maturity. 1019 00:56:09,355 --> 00:56:11,855 One can imagine other things that are a function of the path 1020 00:56:11,855 --> 00:56:12,435 or whatever. 1021 00:56:12,435 --> 00:56:14,580 But this is a particular derivative price. 1022 00:56:14,580 --> 00:56:19,860 European derivative prices are determined by calls. 1023 00:56:19,860 --> 00:56:23,970 OK, so that's kind of nice-- sort of obvious, elegant. 1024 00:56:23,970 --> 00:56:28,890 There's two other ways of looking at this, though. 1025 00:56:28,890 --> 00:56:42,190 If I think about my function g-- so consider function g-- OK, 1026 00:56:42,190 --> 00:56:47,330 so that determines my derivative. 1027 00:56:47,330 --> 00:56:49,450 So it determines, defines the derivative 1028 00:56:49,450 --> 00:56:50,760 by its payout at maturity. 1029 00:56:50,760 --> 00:56:54,270 Let's just graph it. 1030 00:56:54,270 --> 00:56:57,190 OK, so it might look-- let's just 1031 00:56:57,190 --> 00:56:59,290 assume first it's piecewise linear, 1032 00:56:59,290 --> 00:57:07,352 so it looks like-- so suppose this is g. 1033 00:57:13,490 --> 00:57:15,750 Well you can kind of see I can replicate 1034 00:57:15,750 --> 00:57:21,870 this portfolio, or this option, by a portfolio of calls-- 1035 00:57:21,870 --> 00:57:24,410 in fact, a linear combination of calls. 1036 00:57:24,410 --> 00:57:28,040 Right, I have no calls, but if this is say K_1, 1037 00:57:28,040 --> 00:57:37,260 this is K_2, K_3, K_4, K_5, et cetera. 1038 00:57:37,260 --> 00:57:41,065 You can see what the portfolio of calls 1039 00:57:41,065 --> 00:57:43,770 will be in order to replicate this payout at maturity. 1040 00:57:43,770 --> 00:57:46,670 There'll be a certain amount of calls with strike K_1, 1041 00:57:46,670 --> 00:57:49,750 so that the slope is right, minus a certain amount of K_2 1042 00:57:49,750 --> 00:57:52,480 to get this slope, plus a certain about of K_3, 1043 00:57:52,480 --> 00:57:55,370 minus K_4, minus K_5, plus K_6, et cetera. 1044 00:57:55,370 --> 00:57:56,880 So, in this case, if the piecewise 1045 00:57:56,880 --> 00:58:13,860 linear g, replicating portfolio of calls, it's obvious. 1046 00:58:18,380 --> 00:58:22,610 So if I can replicate the payout exactly at maturity, 1047 00:58:22,610 --> 00:58:26,830 the price at time little t of this derivative 1048 00:58:26,830 --> 00:58:31,220 must be the price at little t of the replicating portfolio. 1049 00:58:31,220 --> 00:58:35,955 That's actually a-- I'll do that early on in my class, 1050 00:58:35,955 --> 00:58:39,250 and of the 100 people, everyone says, OK, that makes sense. 1051 00:58:39,250 --> 00:58:42,879 And someone says, does that always have to be the case? 1052 00:58:42,879 --> 00:58:44,920 And it's actually a really, really good question. 1053 00:58:44,920 --> 00:58:48,680 Here, I was about to just hand wave over it. 1054 00:58:48,680 --> 00:58:52,530 Is it the case that if I have one derivative contract 1055 00:58:52,530 --> 00:58:57,770 with this payout at maturity, and I have a linear combination 1056 00:58:57,770 --> 00:59:01,340 of calls with the identical payout at maturity, 1057 00:59:01,340 --> 00:59:05,610 capital T, must these two portfolios have 1058 00:59:05,610 --> 00:59:07,470 the same value at little t? 1059 00:59:11,810 --> 00:59:14,424 Well, one would think so, because they're 1060 00:59:14,424 --> 00:59:15,840 both the same at maturity, so they 1061 00:59:15,840 --> 00:59:17,006 must both be the same thing. 1062 00:59:17,006 --> 00:59:18,620 They're just constructed differently. 1063 00:59:18,620 --> 00:59:20,240 And the assumption of no arbitrage-- 1064 00:59:20,240 --> 00:59:23,150 which underpins everything, in some sense, what we're doing-- 1065 00:59:23,150 --> 00:59:27,370 would allow you to say yes, indeed, that is true. 1066 00:59:27,370 --> 00:59:30,860 And in fact, it's actually the fundamental of finance, right? 1067 00:59:30,860 --> 00:59:33,030 If two things are worth a dollar in a year's time, 1068 00:59:33,030 --> 00:59:36,409 they're going to be worth the same today. 1069 00:59:36,409 --> 00:59:37,450 That's what we're saying. 1070 00:59:37,450 --> 00:59:40,030 If you can match the portfolio at t, that is actually 1071 00:59:40,030 --> 00:59:44,970 the definition of-- it follows immediately from no arbitrage. 1072 00:59:44,970 --> 00:59:51,230 What has been interesting in finance, especially since 2008, 1073 00:59:51,230 --> 00:59:57,470 is that that-- this assumption-- has broken down. 1074 00:59:57,470 --> 01:00:01,060 In other words, I can hold a portfolio of things 1075 01:00:01,060 --> 01:00:05,220 when aggregated have exactly this payout, 1076 01:00:05,220 --> 01:00:09,840 against an option with exactly this payout, 1077 01:00:09,840 --> 01:00:13,171 and be paid for that. 1078 01:00:13,171 --> 01:00:15,670 And this is actually really-- it's a very fascinating thing, 1079 01:00:15,670 --> 01:00:18,630 to think about actually, the dynamics of financial markets 1080 01:00:18,630 --> 01:00:20,030 when arbitrage can break down. 1081 01:00:20,030 --> 01:00:23,160 What is the main theme here is that when 1082 01:00:23,160 --> 01:00:29,520 capital T is a long way in the future-- 10 years, 1083 01:00:29,520 --> 01:00:33,120 20 years-- there's nothing to stop 1084 01:00:33,120 --> 01:00:36,230 the price of the option and the replicating portfolio 1085 01:00:36,230 --> 01:00:39,240 going arbitrarily wide, other than people believing 1086 01:00:39,240 --> 01:00:40,560 that it has to be equal. 1087 01:00:43,430 --> 01:00:46,060 The only way you can guarantee the two things to be equal 1088 01:00:46,060 --> 01:00:52,060 is by holding it until capital T-- for 10 years, 20 years. 1089 01:00:52,060 --> 01:00:56,420 In the meantime, those prices can move. 1090 01:00:56,420 --> 01:01:01,000 Empirically, they've been shown to move away from each other. 1091 01:01:01,000 --> 01:01:04,670 So there's actually a deep economic question here. 1092 01:01:04,670 --> 01:01:09,950 So if there is the presence of arbitrage in the markets, 1093 01:01:09,950 --> 01:01:11,969 then arbitrage can be arbitrarily big. 1094 01:01:11,969 --> 01:01:14,260 Because you're saying there aren't enough-- there's not 1095 01:01:14,260 --> 01:01:17,230 enough capital, or that's not enough risk capital, 1096 01:01:17,230 --> 01:01:21,200 for people to come in and say, OK, these two things 1097 01:01:21,200 --> 01:01:23,720 have to be worth the same in 10 year's time. 1098 01:01:23,720 --> 01:01:28,889 Therefore, I'm prepared to buy one $1 cheaper than the other. 1099 01:01:28,889 --> 01:01:31,180 It's actually a question really relevant to the Harvard 1100 01:01:31,180 --> 01:01:31,679 endowment. 1101 01:01:31,679 --> 01:01:32,910 We're a long-term investor. 1102 01:01:32,910 --> 01:01:35,310 You say, why doesn't the Harvard endowment, 1103 01:01:35,310 --> 01:01:38,646 if these two things are $1 apart, 1104 01:01:38,646 --> 01:01:40,020 buy the things that's $1 cheaper, 1105 01:01:40,020 --> 01:01:41,976 and just hold them 10 years, make the dollar? 1106 01:01:41,976 --> 01:01:43,490 Well, we'd like to, but if we think 1107 01:01:43,490 --> 01:01:45,260 they're going to be $1 apart, and they're going to go to $10 1108 01:01:45,260 --> 01:01:47,790 apart, we don't want to buy them at $1 apart. 1109 01:01:47,790 --> 01:01:49,316 We want to buy them at $10 apart. 1110 01:01:49,316 --> 01:01:51,570 I mean, yes, we're a long-term investor, 1111 01:01:51,570 --> 01:01:54,357 but we care about our annual returns, or five-year returns. 1112 01:01:54,357 --> 01:01:55,690 Suppose this is a 20-year trade. 1113 01:01:55,690 --> 01:01:58,900 This is very prevalent when these things are 20 years out. 1114 01:01:58,900 --> 01:02:01,630 Anyway, it's a whole-- this is-- it's a little bit-- it's 1115 01:02:01,630 --> 01:02:03,100 a foundational issue. 1116 01:02:03,100 --> 01:02:04,600 It's this thing where it could shake 1117 01:02:04,600 --> 01:02:06,849 the foundational underpinnings of quantitative finance 1118 01:02:06,849 --> 01:02:09,400 if you don't allow this replicating portfolio to have 1119 01:02:09,400 --> 01:02:11,182 the same price as the actual option. 1120 01:02:11,182 --> 01:02:13,390 But mathematically, you can see you can replicate it, 1121 01:02:13,390 --> 01:02:15,200 certainly at capital T, and therefore 1122 01:02:15,200 --> 01:02:18,280 the price at time little t is just the linear combination 1123 01:02:18,280 --> 01:02:19,690 of call prices. 1124 01:02:19,690 --> 01:02:20,830 OK, so let's assume that. 1125 01:02:20,830 --> 01:02:23,531 And then obviously, continuous function 1126 01:02:23,531 --> 01:02:25,030 can be arbitrarily well approximated 1127 01:02:25,030 --> 01:02:26,750 by piecewise linear function. 1128 01:02:26,750 --> 01:02:33,270 Therefore, any function at time-- 1129 01:02:33,270 --> 01:02:37,300 any function of this form-- a derivative 1130 01:02:37,300 --> 01:02:40,809 when compared to that form can be replicated 1131 01:02:40,809 --> 01:02:42,100 by a portfolio of call options. 1132 01:02:42,100 --> 01:02:45,270 So we can sort of hand wave to kind of say, 1133 01:02:45,270 --> 01:02:50,710 this must be true-- the calls are a spanning set. 1134 01:02:50,710 --> 01:02:52,690 There's another way to look at it, which is-- I 1135 01:02:52,690 --> 01:02:56,960 just-- like from calculus, where we can actually make explicit 1136 01:02:56,960 --> 01:03:01,740 what this spanning-- what this portfolio of calls looks 1137 01:03:01,740 --> 01:03:03,550 like in the arbitrary case. 1138 01:03:03,550 --> 01:03:05,535 So let me just do that. 1139 01:03:08,770 --> 01:03:12,940 So you can sort of see, there must be a linear combination 1140 01:03:12,940 --> 01:03:15,800 by this for a piecewise linear. 1141 01:03:15,800 --> 01:03:18,140 Therefore in the limit, any continuous function 1142 01:03:18,140 --> 01:03:20,510 must be able to be replicated by calls. 1143 01:03:20,510 --> 01:03:21,720 How many of each? 1144 01:03:21,720 --> 01:03:33,860 Well, there's actually a very, very simple result. 1145 01:03:33,860 --> 01:03:37,060 That is as follows-- and, well, let's just 1146 01:03:37,060 --> 01:03:40,040 write down an exact Taylor series to the second order. 1147 01:03:40,040 --> 01:03:47,130 So this is-- so for any function with second derivative, 1148 01:03:47,130 --> 01:03:52,659 let's just write down a Taylor series-- the first two terms. 1149 01:03:52,659 --> 01:03:54,450 And let's put the second term-- we can just 1150 01:03:54,450 --> 01:03:58,740 do an exact second-order term, so 0 1151 01:03:58,740 --> 01:04:08,310 to infinity x minus c plus g double prime of c dc. 1152 01:04:08,310 --> 01:04:11,560 c is my dummy variable. 1153 01:04:11,560 --> 01:04:13,817 Actually, I've gone to plus notation. 1154 01:04:13,817 --> 01:04:15,025 Here's the max of this and 0. 1155 01:04:18,530 --> 01:04:20,470 OK, that's an exact Taylor series, 1156 01:04:20,470 --> 01:04:22,370 true for any-- it's not an approximation. 1157 01:04:22,370 --> 01:04:22,950 That's exact. 1158 01:04:22,950 --> 01:04:24,600 You just integrate the right-hand side by parts 1159 01:04:24,600 --> 01:04:25,950 if you want to verify it. 1160 01:04:25,950 --> 01:04:28,210 Maybe it's obvious to you, but I'm 1161 01:04:28,210 --> 01:04:30,404 so used to just doing non-exact Taylor series. 1162 01:04:30,404 --> 01:04:31,570 So this is the second order. 1163 01:04:31,570 --> 01:04:35,190 So this holds for any g exactly. 1164 01:04:35,190 --> 01:04:37,720 And now I'm just going to make one little change, which 1165 01:04:37,720 --> 01:04:39,855 sort of might make obvious what we're trying to do. 1166 01:04:39,855 --> 01:04:42,230 I'm just going to take this dummy variable c, which we're 1167 01:04:42,230 --> 01:04:48,500 integrating over from 0 to infinity, and just call it K. 1168 01:04:48,500 --> 01:04:50,694 We can certainly do that. 1169 01:04:50,694 --> 01:04:52,860 All right, this now looks like the payout of a call. 1170 01:04:56,304 --> 01:04:57,720 It's the payout of the call price. 1171 01:04:57,720 --> 01:04:59,620 Now, I don't want to be integrating. 1172 01:04:59,620 --> 01:05:04,010 Remember, if I want to actually get the call price, 1173 01:05:04,010 --> 01:05:06,870 I take the expected value of this. 1174 01:05:06,870 --> 01:05:10,970 I integrate x over x with respect to its density. 1175 01:05:10,970 --> 01:05:14,670 This is g of a payout function of x. 1176 01:05:14,670 --> 01:05:17,607 Here I'm integrating over K, so I'm 1177 01:05:17,607 --> 01:05:18,940 doing something a bit different. 1178 01:05:18,940 --> 01:05:22,470 But this is the call option payout. 1179 01:05:22,470 --> 01:05:23,230 So this holds. 1180 01:05:23,230 --> 01:05:26,200 It's a linear equation, obviously. 1181 01:05:26,200 --> 01:05:30,260 And of course, expectation is a linear operator. 1182 01:05:30,260 --> 01:05:35,165 So I'm just going to take, well, what are the two steps? 1183 01:05:35,165 --> 01:05:36,790 First of all, I'm just going to replace 1184 01:05:36,790 --> 01:05:42,060 x with my random variable S sub T. So that I can do. 1185 01:05:46,230 --> 01:05:48,850 This also holds. 1186 01:05:48,850 --> 01:05:51,100 And formally, of course, S sub T is a random variable, 1187 01:05:51,100 --> 01:05:53,516 so it's a function from the sample space of the real line. 1188 01:05:53,516 --> 01:05:56,170 But this holds for every point on the sample space. 1189 01:05:56,170 --> 01:05:58,310 So I can write down this equation 1190 01:05:58,310 --> 01:05:59,351 between random variables. 1191 01:06:06,900 --> 01:06:10,220 Here it's just the integral over dK. 1192 01:06:10,220 --> 01:06:11,180 So that holds. 1193 01:06:11,180 --> 01:06:16,090 Now I'm going to take the expectation operator. 1194 01:06:16,090 --> 01:06:27,470 So take discounted expected value, of each side. 1195 01:06:32,546 --> 01:06:34,670 So in other words, what is my operator [INAUDIBLE]? 1196 01:06:34,670 --> 01:06:41,696 It looks like Z(t, T), expected value of, given S_t. 1197 01:06:41,696 --> 01:06:42,196 All right? 1198 01:06:45,690 --> 01:06:48,630 OK, so this one is a discounted expected value. 1199 01:06:48,630 --> 01:06:50,094 That's the price. 1200 01:06:55,470 --> 01:07:01,410 So this becomes price of the derivative with payout 1201 01:07:01,410 --> 01:07:03,567 at maturity g. 1202 01:07:03,567 --> 01:07:04,900 All right, what do we have here? 1203 01:07:04,900 --> 01:07:07,570 Well, first we've got a constant. 1204 01:07:07,570 --> 01:07:17,768 So we've got a constant times-- OK, so that's a constant. 1205 01:07:22,450 --> 01:07:27,440 OK, now we've got the discounted expected stock price. 1206 01:07:27,440 --> 01:07:29,020 A little bit of thought on the terms 1207 01:07:29,020 --> 01:07:30,686 of the Fundamental Theorem will show you 1208 01:07:30,686 --> 01:07:33,745 that the discounted expected stock price under this operator 1209 01:07:33,745 --> 01:07:35,336 is the current stock price. 1210 01:07:35,336 --> 01:07:40,930 It's actually non-trivial, but just think of the stock itself 1211 01:07:40,930 --> 01:07:43,520 as a derivative, with the payout S, 1212 01:07:43,520 --> 01:07:45,950 and apply the Fundamental Theorem. 1213 01:07:45,950 --> 01:07:49,220 This has to be the case, because a replicating portfolio 1214 01:07:49,220 --> 01:07:52,800 of the stock is just a holding of the stock. 1215 01:07:52,800 --> 01:07:55,580 Plus-- and then we just take the integral. 1216 01:07:55,580 --> 01:08:05,910 So the expectation inside the integral-- OK, so now I've got 1217 01:08:05,910 --> 01:08:08,455 discounted expected payout of this. 1218 01:08:08,455 --> 01:08:10,490 And the discounted expected payout of this 1219 01:08:10,490 --> 01:08:21,930 is just the call price, with strike K. 1220 01:08:21,930 --> 01:08:23,689 OK, so I really like this formula. 1221 01:08:23,689 --> 01:08:28,399 In some sense, there's nothing too complicated about how 1222 01:08:28,399 --> 01:08:30,250 to derive it. 1223 01:08:30,250 --> 01:08:36,250 But it says explicitly now, how do I replicate an arbitrary 1224 01:08:36,250 --> 01:08:40,990 derivative product with payout g of x or g of S at maturity? 1225 01:08:40,990 --> 01:08:41,810 Well, it's clear. 1226 01:08:41,810 --> 01:08:48,399 I replicate it by g(0) zero-coupon bonds. 1227 01:08:48,399 --> 01:08:52,650 So I have g(0) of zero coupon bonds. 1228 01:08:52,650 --> 01:08:54,170 That's this. 1229 01:08:54,170 --> 01:08:59,450 I have g prime zero of stock-- that's this. 1230 01:08:59,450 --> 01:09:02,270 And I have this linear combination of calls. 1231 01:09:12,160 --> 01:09:15,779 So there-- this kind of makes sense, right? 1232 01:09:15,779 --> 01:09:18,870 You want the zero-coupon bond amount is just 1233 01:09:18,870 --> 01:09:21,229 the intercept of g. 1234 01:09:21,229 --> 01:09:24,960 The number of stocks is just the slope of g at 0. 1235 01:09:24,960 --> 01:09:28,882 And then I have this linear combination of call prices. 1236 01:09:28,882 --> 01:09:32,490 I've just proved that by taking this, and taking 1237 01:09:32,490 --> 01:09:35,160 expected values. 1238 01:09:35,160 --> 01:09:44,399 So this is sort of looking at the duality of option prices 1239 01:09:44,399 --> 01:09:45,899 and probabilities in different ways. 1240 01:09:45,899 --> 01:09:49,160 But then, also how calls span everything. 1241 01:09:49,160 --> 01:09:54,000 So the calls, in some sense, are the primitive information. 1242 01:09:54,000 --> 01:09:56,240 Once I know all call option prices, 1243 01:09:56,240 --> 01:09:59,890 I know the probability distribution exactly. 1244 01:09:59,890 --> 01:10:03,300 So there are a couple of sort of interesting further questions 1245 01:10:03,300 --> 01:10:06,600 you might want to pose. 1246 01:10:06,600 --> 01:10:09,880 We seem to have done everything here 1247 01:10:09,880 --> 01:10:14,140 with regard to the distribution at time capital T. 1248 01:10:14,140 --> 01:10:14,880 And that's true. 1249 01:10:14,880 --> 01:10:15,754 I know all the calls. 1250 01:10:15,754 --> 01:10:18,735 I know the distribution at time capital T. 1251 01:10:18,735 --> 01:10:19,610 I know all the calls. 1252 01:10:19,610 --> 01:10:24,810 I know the price of any option with a payout defined solely 1253 01:10:24,810 --> 01:10:27,470 by a function at capital T. 1254 01:10:27,470 --> 01:10:30,590 But I said nothing about the path that 1255 01:10:30,590 --> 01:10:34,300 takes the stock from today until capital T. 1256 01:10:34,300 --> 01:10:37,170 So I'm just going to leave you with two things to think about. 1257 01:10:39,834 --> 01:10:41,500 Actually, it's one thing to think about. 1258 01:10:44,570 --> 01:10:45,920 Two people thought about a lot. 1259 01:10:50,850 --> 01:10:54,170 And it's the following question, which now we'll 1260 01:10:54,170 --> 01:10:57,860 start transitioning into stochastic calculus, 1261 01:10:57,860 --> 01:10:59,900 and stochastic processes a little bit. 1262 01:10:59,900 --> 01:11:03,982 So we know-- let's just imagine two times. 1263 01:11:09,290 --> 01:11:22,190 So suppose we know-- so we know the set of all call prices 1264 01:11:22,190 --> 01:11:32,190 with maturity T_1, for all K, and the set of all call 1265 01:11:32,190 --> 01:11:41,560 prices with maturity T_2 for all K. 1266 01:11:41,560 --> 01:11:43,810 OK, so then we know the distribution. 1267 01:11:43,810 --> 01:11:45,960 Well, there are two distributions. 1268 01:11:45,960 --> 01:11:48,597 We know the distribution of T_1 given S_t, 1269 01:11:48,597 --> 01:12:00,970 and-- but do we know the distribution 1270 01:12:00,970 --> 01:12:03,930 of the stock at T_2 given T_1? 1271 01:12:10,930 --> 01:12:23,250 More of a general point-- suppose I know this for all T. 1272 01:12:23,250 --> 01:12:24,800 Let's put T_0 here. 1273 01:12:27,800 --> 01:12:32,365 OK, I know all option prices of all maturities and all strikes. 1274 01:12:35,230 --> 01:12:52,990 Can I determine the stochastic process for S_T over this time? 1275 01:12:52,990 --> 01:12:56,920 Is the underlying stochastic process for the stock price 1276 01:12:56,920 --> 01:12:59,500 fully determined by knowing all call option 1277 01:12:59,500 --> 01:13:01,250 prices for all strikes and all maturities? 1278 01:13:04,460 --> 01:13:07,320 The marginal distributions or the conditional distributions 1279 01:13:07,320 --> 01:13:08,980 for all maturities are determined, 1280 01:13:08,980 --> 01:13:12,416 because we know that here. 1281 01:13:12,416 --> 01:13:13,790 Well, you'll probably see this is 1282 01:13:13,790 --> 01:13:16,030 a rephrasing of a finite-dimensional problem 1283 01:13:16,030 --> 01:13:17,802 from probability. 1284 01:13:17,802 --> 01:13:18,510 The answer is no. 1285 01:13:25,190 --> 01:13:26,890 And the reason to think about is, 1286 01:13:26,890 --> 01:13:29,500 if I know all the-- my intuition for this 1287 01:13:29,500 --> 01:13:34,000 is if I know all the distributions that-- 1288 01:13:34,000 --> 01:13:36,900 think about just a denser and denser grid of times 1289 01:13:36,900 --> 01:13:39,400 that I know the distribution of-- getting closer and closer. 1290 01:13:39,400 --> 01:13:44,757 I can still allow the stock to flip instantaneously quickly. 1291 01:13:44,757 --> 01:13:47,090 Imagine they're all essentially symmetric distributions, 1292 01:13:47,090 --> 01:13:49,048 and they're all roughly the same expanding out. 1293 01:13:49,048 --> 01:13:54,060 I can imagine the stock flipping discontinuously 1294 01:13:54,060 --> 01:13:56,220 over an arbitrarily small time interval. 1295 01:13:56,220 --> 01:14:00,930 So without a constraint on the continuity of this process, 1296 01:14:00,930 --> 01:14:03,190 or mathematical constraints on this process, 1297 01:14:03,190 --> 01:14:07,870 you can't determine the actual process for the stock, 1298 01:14:07,870 --> 01:14:11,920 even given all the option prices-- call option prices. 1299 01:14:11,920 --> 01:14:15,386 So there are two-- so Emanuel Derman, 1300 01:14:15,386 --> 01:14:20,390 who was at Goldman Sachs, now at Columbia-- and Bruno 1301 01:14:20,390 --> 01:14:24,530 Dupire-- who's, I think, still at Bloomberg-- 1302 01:14:24,530 --> 01:14:27,360 this is the early '90s-- basically determined 1303 01:14:27,360 --> 01:14:28,665 the conditions that you need. 1304 01:14:28,665 --> 01:14:30,680 And the basic conditions are that just the stock 1305 01:14:30,680 --> 01:14:32,412 has to be a diffusion process. 1306 01:14:32,412 --> 01:14:36,100 If it is a diffusion process-- the random term is 1307 01:14:36,100 --> 01:14:39,130 Brownian motion-- then it is, actually, fully determined. 1308 01:14:39,130 --> 01:14:41,690 And it's a really nice, elegant result. 1309 01:14:41,690 --> 01:14:44,360 So this is what gets mathematically quite 1310 01:14:44,360 --> 01:14:47,740 nice, and a little tricky. 1311 01:14:47,740 --> 01:14:51,530 But there's a practical implication of this, 1312 01:14:51,530 --> 01:14:58,770 as well, which is in practice, I will know a finite subset 1313 01:14:58,770 --> 01:15:01,260 of call options. 1314 01:15:01,260 --> 01:15:04,510 Those prices will be available to me in the market. 1315 01:15:04,510 --> 01:15:06,750 So they will be given. 1316 01:15:06,750 --> 01:15:11,400 So one thing I know for sure is that even 1317 01:15:11,400 --> 01:15:15,690 with a very densely set of call option prices, 1318 01:15:15,690 --> 01:15:18,330 there will be some other derivative prices 1319 01:15:18,330 --> 01:15:21,840 whose price is not exactly determined 1320 01:15:21,840 --> 01:15:22,810 by that set of calls. 1321 01:15:22,810 --> 01:15:25,660 Because in particular, I know that the set of calls 1322 01:15:25,660 --> 01:15:28,050 does not determine the underlying stochastic process, 1323 01:15:28,050 --> 01:15:30,050 even if I knew all of them. 1324 01:15:30,050 --> 01:15:33,140 So that's a very important thing for traders to understand, 1325 01:15:33,140 --> 01:15:36,690 is that even if I know a lot of market information-- so I'm 1326 01:15:36,690 --> 01:15:39,690 given here are the prices of a large number 1327 01:15:39,690 --> 01:15:43,060 of European options, European call options I can trade-- 1328 01:15:43,060 --> 01:15:45,940 there may be a complex or nonstandard derivative product, 1329 01:15:45,940 --> 01:15:49,160 whose price is not determined uniquely, simply 1330 01:15:49,160 --> 01:15:50,680 by knowing those options. 1331 01:15:50,680 --> 01:15:52,155 And that is one of the challenges 1332 01:15:52,155 --> 01:15:55,730 for some of the quant groups. 1333 01:15:55,730 --> 01:16:00,190 So anyway, with that, that is all I wanted to convey. 1334 01:16:00,190 --> 01:16:01,660 I'm happy to take some questions. 1335 01:16:01,660 --> 01:16:04,474 And thank you for your time. 1336 01:16:04,474 --> 01:16:05,473 Thank you for having me. 1337 01:16:05,473 --> 01:16:06,952 I appreciate it. 1338 01:16:06,952 --> 01:16:13,854 [APPLAUSE] 1339 01:16:13,854 --> 01:16:16,040 AUDIENCE: Yeah, I have-- I was just 1340 01:16:16,040 --> 01:16:19,950 wondering, so you the call, or the set of all calls 1341 01:16:19,950 --> 01:16:23,797 basically spans the space of all possible payouts, right? 1342 01:16:23,797 --> 01:16:24,630 STEPHEN BLYTHE: Yes. 1343 01:16:24,630 --> 01:16:26,005 AUDIENCE: So I was just wondering 1344 01:16:26,005 --> 01:16:30,700 if maybe if we could change, and select some other such basis 1345 01:16:30,700 --> 01:16:32,457 for spanning it? 1346 01:16:32,457 --> 01:16:34,040 Instead of call, maybe some other kind 1347 01:16:34,040 --> 01:16:39,260 of basic payoff that could still span the same thing, 1348 01:16:39,260 --> 01:16:42,190 and maybe it's more easily tradable, or something? 1349 01:16:42,190 --> 01:16:44,820 STEPHEN BLYTHE: Yeah, that's a good-- there must be many, 1350 01:16:44,820 --> 01:16:48,060 if I can-- but this, given that this 1351 01:16:48,060 --> 01:16:54,140 is the simplest expansion of the function g, 1352 01:16:54,140 --> 01:16:56,650 an arbitrary function g, and the second term comes in 1353 01:16:56,650 --> 01:17:01,300 with this call payout, gives us this elegance. 1354 01:17:01,300 --> 01:17:04,507 Of course, if I know all the digitals, 1355 01:17:04,507 --> 01:17:06,340 I know the cumulative distribution function, 1356 01:17:06,340 --> 01:17:07,550 and therefore, I know the density. 1357 01:17:07,550 --> 01:17:09,050 So I mean, the digitals do the same. 1358 01:17:09,050 --> 01:17:10,784 And in fact, Arrow-Debreu securities, 1359 01:17:10,784 --> 01:17:13,200 which is building blocks, which is something that pays off 1360 01:17:13,200 --> 01:17:16,200 one in a particular state, sample state, 1361 01:17:16,200 --> 01:17:18,508 also are building blocks. 1362 01:17:18,508 --> 01:17:20,047 AUDIENCE: [INAUDIBLE]. 1363 01:17:20,047 --> 01:17:21,630 STEPHEN BLYTHE: I mean, sometimes, you 1364 01:17:21,630 --> 01:17:23,440 could think about an arbitrary basis that 1365 01:17:23,440 --> 01:17:27,160 will span-- an arbitrary basis of functions that will 1366 01:17:27,160 --> 01:17:28,560 span any continuous function. 1367 01:17:28,560 --> 01:17:31,709 And sometimes, you can do it in any polynomial expansion. 1368 01:17:31,709 --> 01:17:33,500 If I have a price and any of those payouts, 1369 01:17:33,500 --> 01:17:35,356 and I've got my spanning set. 1370 01:17:35,356 --> 01:17:36,730 But this is the most elegant one. 1371 01:17:41,380 --> 01:17:42,464 Yeah, next question there. 1372 01:17:42,464 --> 01:17:44,713 AUDIENCE: I have a question about the last [INAUDIBLE] 1373 01:17:44,713 --> 01:17:45,295 mentioned. 1374 01:17:45,295 --> 01:17:50,225 [INAUDIBLE] because market's incomplete, 1375 01:17:50,225 --> 01:17:54,255 so you can not sort of use call option 1376 01:17:54,255 --> 01:17:57,412 to replicate the stock itself. 1377 01:17:57,412 --> 01:17:59,120 STEPHEN BLYTHE: You can use a call option 1378 01:17:59,120 --> 01:18:02,467 to replicate a stock. 1379 01:18:02,467 --> 01:18:03,800 As long as you have zero-coupon. 1380 01:18:03,800 --> 01:18:06,580 You can see from here, I can just reorganize everything here 1381 01:18:06,580 --> 01:18:09,640 to zero-coupon bond stock, and a set of calls 1382 01:18:09,640 --> 01:18:12,880 will span anything-- with maturity T. What they're 1383 01:18:12,880 --> 01:18:17,080 sort of saying is, if I have this strange process 1384 01:18:17,080 --> 01:18:21,360 with jumps, and flips, and discontinuities, 1385 01:18:21,360 --> 01:18:24,320 then the market is incomplete, I guess is what this is saying. 1386 01:18:24,320 --> 01:18:25,860 AUDIENCE: OK, yeah, so [INAUDIBLE] 1387 01:18:25,860 --> 01:18:27,130 is due to the incompleteness. 1388 01:18:27,130 --> 01:18:28,546 STEPHEN BLYTHE: Yeah, in the sense 1389 01:18:28,546 --> 01:18:31,700 of most finance-- in fact, all continuous-time finance 1390 01:18:31,700 --> 01:18:33,660 will assume there's some diffusion 1391 01:18:33,660 --> 01:18:38,540 process for-- some process for stock, 1392 01:18:38,540 --> 01:18:41,530 which has some Brownian motion. 1393 01:18:41,530 --> 01:18:43,030 There's some function here, and some 1394 01:18:43,030 --> 01:18:45,070 function for the drift term. 1395 01:18:45,070 --> 01:18:48,890 In that case, then all the call prices do determine. 1396 01:18:48,890 --> 01:18:52,986 If you think there's some exogenous flipping parameter-- 1397 01:18:52,986 --> 01:18:54,110 that's my intuition for it. 1398 01:18:54,110 --> 01:18:56,110 So there's some-- that's why this is incomplete. 1399 01:18:56,110 --> 01:18:57,235 So this will not determine. 1400 01:18:57,235 --> 01:18:59,443 So in particular, I could know all these call prices. 1401 01:18:59,443 --> 01:19:01,900 Then I could determine a particular derivative product. 1402 01:19:01,900 --> 01:19:03,680 It could be the number of times that 1403 01:19:03,680 --> 01:19:05,170 in an arbitrarily small interval, 1404 01:19:05,170 --> 01:19:06,904 the stock flips this many times. 1405 01:19:06,904 --> 01:19:08,820 I mean, there's some-- you can create whatever 1406 01:19:08,820 --> 01:19:10,319 you like for a derivative that would 1407 01:19:10,319 --> 01:19:11,846 be incomplete for these calls. 1408 01:19:11,846 --> 01:19:14,220 AUDIENCE: So in this case, go back to a previous question 1409 01:19:14,220 --> 01:19:17,200 as we just mentioned-- the second-order derivative 1410 01:19:17,200 --> 01:19:20,295 of a call option with respect to a strike 1411 01:19:20,295 --> 01:19:22,510 is [INAUDIBLE] risk-neutral density. 1412 01:19:22,510 --> 01:19:26,555 So in this case, it was not-- that risk-neutral density, 1413 01:19:26,555 --> 01:19:28,630 or a particular instance of that, 1414 01:19:28,630 --> 01:19:30,089 rather, is not uniquely determined. 1415 01:19:30,089 --> 01:19:31,921 STEPHEN BLYTHE: No, the risk-neutral density 1416 01:19:31,921 --> 01:19:32,930 is uniquely determined. 1417 01:19:32,930 --> 01:19:35,670 The stochastic process for S_t over all time 1418 01:19:35,670 --> 01:19:38,220 is not uniquely determined. 1419 01:19:38,220 --> 01:19:42,530 So this is uniquely determined by call option prices. 1420 01:19:45,490 --> 01:19:48,814 That is uniquely determined. 1421 01:19:48,814 --> 01:19:50,480 But knowing the conditional distribution 1422 01:19:50,480 --> 01:19:55,760 of S capital T given S little t doesn't determine 1423 01:19:55,760 --> 01:19:57,064 the process of the stock price. 1424 01:19:57,064 --> 01:19:59,355 To get there-- I can think of infinitely many processes 1425 01:19:59,355 --> 01:20:03,580 of the stock price that can give rise to this distribution. 1426 01:20:03,580 --> 01:20:04,824 That's what's not determined. 1427 01:20:09,280 --> 01:20:11,540 The terminal distribution is uniquely determined 1428 01:20:11,540 --> 01:20:13,653 by the call option prices-- nothing else. 1429 01:20:13,653 --> 01:20:15,920 AUDIENCE: So in this case, if we take Z over theta, 1430 01:20:15,920 --> 01:20:19,401 so we'll get a particular risk-neutral density 1431 01:20:19,401 --> 01:20:20,590 for each particular stock? 1432 01:20:20,590 --> 01:20:21,881 STEPHEN BLYTHE: That's correct. 1433 01:20:25,465 --> 01:20:26,590 Right, thank you very much. 1434 01:20:26,590 --> 01:20:28,140 Appreciate it.